The Conquest of Bread
The Conquest of BreadPREFACESecond PrefaceCHAPTER ICHAPTER IICHAPTER IIICHAPTER IVCHAPTER VCHAPTER VICHAPTER VIICHAPTER VIIICHAPTER IXCHAPTER XCHAPTER XICHAPTER XIICHAPTER XIIICHAPTER XIVCHAPTER XVCHAPTER XVICHAPTER XVIICopyright
The Conquest of Bread
Peter Kropotkin
PREFACE
One of the current objections to Communism, and Socialism
altogether, is that the idea is so old, and yet it has never been
realized. Schemes of ideal States haunted the thinkers of Ancient
Greece; later on, the early Christians joined in communist groups;
centuries later, large communist brotherhoods came into existence
during the Reform movement. Then, the same ideals were revived
during the great English and French Revolutions; and finally, quite
lately, in 1848, a revolution, inspired to a great extent with
Socialist ideals, took place in France. "And yet, you see," we are
told, "how far away is still the realization of your schemes. Don't
you think that there is some fundamental error in your
understanding of human nature and its needs?"At first sight this objection seems very serious. However,
the moment we consider human history more attentively, it loses its
strength. We see, first, that hundreds of millions of men have
succeeded in maintaining amongst themselves, in their village
communities, for many hundreds of years, one of the main elements
of Socialism—the common ownership of the chief instrument of
production, the land, and the apportionment of the same according
to the labour capacities of the different families; and we learn
that if the communal possession of the land has been destroyed in
Western Europe, it was not from within, but from without, by the
governments which created a land monopoly in favour of the nobility
and the middle classes. We learn, moreover, that the medieval
cities succeeded in maintaining in their midst, for several
centuries in succession, a certain socialized organization of
production and trade; that these centuries were periods of a rapid
intellectual, industrial, and artistic progress; while the decay of
these communal institutions came mainly from the incapacity of men
of combining the village with the city, the peasant with the
citizen, so as jointly to oppose the growth of the military states,
which destroyed the free cities.The history of mankind, thus understood, does not offer,
then, an argument against Communism. It appears, on the contrary,
as a succession of endeavours to realize some sort of communist
organization, endeavours which were crowned here and there with a
partial success of a certain duration; and all we are authorized to
conclude is, that mankind has not yet found the proper form for
combining, on communistic principles, agriculture with a suddenly
developed industry and a rapidly growing international trade. The
latter appears especially as a disturbing element, since it is no
longer individuals only, or cities, that enrich themselves by
distant commerce and export; but whole nations grow rich at the
cost of those nations which lag behind in their industrial
development.These conditions, which began to appear by the end of the
eighteenth century, took, however, their full development in the
nineteenth century only, after the Napoleonic wars came to an end.
And modern Communism has to take them into account.It is now known that the French Revolution, apart from its
political significance, was an attempt made by the French people,
in 1793 and 1794, in three different directions more or less akin
to Socialism. It was, first,the equalization of
fortunes, by means of an income tax and
succession duties, both heavily progressive, as also by a direct
confiscation of the land in order to sub-divide it, and by heavy
war taxes levied upon the rich only. The second attempt was a sort
ofMunicipal Communismas
regards the consumption of some objects of first necessity, bought
by the municipalities, and sold by them at cost price. And the
third attempt was to introduce a widenational
system of rationally established prices of all
commodities, for which the real cost of
production and moderate trade profits had to be taken into account.
The Convention worked hard at this scheme, and had nearly completed
its work, when reaction took the upper hand.It was during this remarkable movement, which has never yet
been properly studied, that modern Socialism was born—Fourierism
with L'Ange, at Lyons, and authoritarian Communism with Buonarroti,
Babeuf, and their comrades. And it was immediately after the Great
Revolution that the three great theoretical founders of modern
Socialism—Fourier, Saint Simon, and Robert Owen, as well as Godwin
(the No-State Socialism)—came forward; while the secret communist
societies, originated from those of Buonarroti and Babeuf, gave
their stamp to militant, authoritarian Communism for the next fifty
years.To be correct, then, we must say that modern Socialism is not
yet a hundred years old, and that, for the first half of these
hundred years, two nations only, which stood at the head of the
industrial movement, i.e., Britain and France, took part in its
elaboration. Both—bleeding at that time from the terrible wounds
inflicted upon them by fifteen years of Napoleonic wars, and both
enveloped in the great European reaction that had come from the
East.In fact, it was only after the Revolution of July, 1830, in
France, and the Reform movement of 1830-1832 in this country, had
begun to shake off that terrible reaction, that the discussion of
Socialism became possible for a few years before the revolution of
1848. And it was during those years that the aspirations of
Fourier, St. Simon, and Robert Owen, worked out by their followers,
took a definite shape, and the different schools of Socialism which
exist nowadays were defined.In Britain, Robert Owen and his followers worked out their
schemes of communist villages, agricultural and industrial at the
same time; immense co-operative associations were started for
creating with their dividends more communist colonies; and the
Great Consolidated Trades' Union was founded—the forerunner of both
the Labour Parties of our days and the International Working-men's
Association.In France, the Fourierist Considérant issued his remarkable
manifesto, which contains, beautifully developed, all the
theoretical considerations upon the growth of Capitalism, which are
now described as "Scientific Socialism." Proudhon worked out his
idea of Anarchism and Mutualism, without State interference. Louis
Blanc published hisOrganization of
Labour, which became later on the programme of
Lassalle. Vidal in France and Lorenz Stein in Germany further
developed, in two remarkable works, published in 1846 and 1847
respectively, the theoretical conceptions of Considérant; and
finally Vidal, and especially Pecqueur, developed in detail the
system of Collectivism, which the former wanted the National
Assembly of 1848 to vote in the shape of laws.However, there is one feature, common to all Socialist
schemes of that period, which must be noted. The three great
founders of Socialism who wrote at the dawn of the nineteenth
century were so entranced by the wide horizons which it opened
before them, that they looked upon it as a new revelation, and upon
themselves as upon the founders of a new religion. Socialism had to
be a religion, and they had to regulate its march, as the heads of
a new church. Besides, writing during the period of reaction which
had followed the French Revolution, and seeing more its failures
than its successes, they did not trust the masses, and they did not
appeal to them for bringing about the changes which they thought
necessary. They put their faith, on the contrary, into some great
ruler, some Socialist Napoleon. He would understand the new
revelation; he would be convinced of its desirability by the
successful experiments of their phalansteries, or associations; and
he would peacefully accomplish by his own authority the revolution
which would bring well-being and happiness to mankind. A military
genius, Napoleon, had just been ruling Europe. Why should not a
social genius come forward, carry Europe with him and translate the
new Gospel into life? That faith was rooted very deep, and it stood
for a long time in the way of Socialism; its traces are even seen
amongst us, down to the present day.It was only during the years 1840-48, when the approach of
the Revolution was felt everywhere, and the proletarians were
beginning to plant the banner of Socialism on the barricades, that
faith in the people began to enter once more the hearts of the
social schemers: faith, on the one side, in Republican Democracy,
and on the other side infreeassociation, in the organizing powers of the working-men
themselves.But then came the Revolution of February, 1848, the
middle-class Republic, and—with it, shattered hopes. Four months
only after the proclamation of the Republic, the June insurrection
of the Paris proletarians broke out, and it was crushed in blood.
The wholesale shooting of the working-men, the mass deportations to
New Guinea, and finally the Napoleoniancoup
d'êtatfollowed. The Socialists were prosecuted
with fury, and the weeding out was so terrible and so thorough that
for the next twelve or fifteen years the very traces of Socialism
disappeared; its literature vanished so completely that even names,
once so familiar before 1848, were entirely forgotten; ideas which
were then current—the stock ideas of the Socialists before
1848—were so wiped out as to be taken, later on, by our generation,
for new discoveries.However, when a new revival began, about 1866, when Communism
and Collectivism once more came forward, it appeared that the
conception as to the means of their realization had undergone a
deep change. The old faith in Political Democracy was dying out,
and the first principles upon which the Paris working-men agreed
with the British trade-unionists and Owenites, when they met in
1862 and 1864, at London, was that "the emancipation of the
working-men must be accomplished by the working-men themselves."
Upon another point they also were agreed. It was that the labour
unions themselves would have to get hold of the instruments of
production, and organize production themselves. The French idea of
the Fourierist and Mutualist "Association" thus joined hands with
Robert Owen's idea of "The Great Consolidated Trades' Union," which
was extended now, so as to become an International Working-men's
Association.Again this new revival of Socialism lasted but a few years.
Soon came the war of 1870-71, the uprising of the Paris Commune—and
again the free development of Socialism was rendered impossible in
France. But while Germany accepted now from the hands of its German
teachers, Marx and Engels, the Socialism of the French
"forty-eighters" that is, the Socialism of Considérant and Louis
Blanc, and the Collectivism of Pecqueur,—France made a further step
forward.In March, 1871, Paris had proclaimed that henceforward it
would not wait for the retardatory portions of France: that it
intended to start within its Commune its own social
development.The movement was too short-lived to give any positive result.
It remained communalist only; it merely asserted the rights of the
Commune to its full autonomy. But the working-classes of the old
International saw at once its historical significance. They
understood that the free commune would be henceforth the medium in
which the ideas of modern Socialism may come to realization. The
free agro-industrial communes, of which so much was spoken in
England and France before 1848, need not be small phalansteries, or
small communities of 2000 persons. They must be vast
agglomerations, like Paris, or, still better, small territories.
These communes would federate to constitute nations in some cases,
even irrespectively of the present national frontiers (like the
Cinque Ports, or the Hansa). At the same time large labour
associations would come into existence for the inter-communal
service of the railways, the docks, and so on.Such were the ideas which began vaguely to circulate after
1871 amongst the thinking working-men, especially in the Latin
countries. In some such organization, the details of which life
itself would settle, the labour circles saw the medium through
which Socialist forms of life could find a much easier realization
than through the seizure of all industrial property by the State,
and the State organization of agriculture and
industry.These are the ideas to which I have endeavoured to give a
more or less definite expression in this book.Looking back now at the years that have passed since this
book was written, I can say in full conscience that its leading
ideas must have been correct. State Socialism has certainly made
considerable progress. State railways, State banking, and State
trade in spirits have been introduced here and there. But every
step made in this direction, even though it resulted in the
cheapening of a given commodity, was found to be a new obstacle in
the struggle of the working-men for their emancipation. So that we
find growing amongst the working-men, especially in Western Europe,
the idea that even the working of such a vast national property as
a railway-net could be much better handled by a Federated Union of
railway employés, than by a State organization.On the other side, we see that countless attempts have been
made all over Europe and America, the leading idea of which is, on
the one side, to get into the hands of the working-men themselves
wide branches of production, and, on the other side, to always
widen in the cities the circles of the functions which the city
performs in the interest of its inhabitants. Trade-unionism, with a
growing tendency towards organizing the different trades
internationally, and of being not only an instrument for the
improvement of the conditions of labour, but also of becoming an
organization which might, at a given moment, take into its hands
the management of production; Co-operation, both for production and
for distribution, both in industry and agriculture, and attempts at
combining both sorts of co-operation in experimental colonies; and
finally, the immensely varied field of the so-called Municipal
Socialism—these are the three directions in which the greatest
amount of creative power has been developed lately.Of course, none of these may, in any degree, be taken as a
substitute for Communism, or even for Socialism, both of which
imply the common possession of the instruments of production. But
we certainly must look at all these attempts as uponexperiments—like those which Owen,
Fourier, and Saint Simon tried in their colonies—experiments which
prepare human thought to conceive some of the practical forms in
which a communist society might find its expression. The synthesis
of all these partial experiments will have to be made some day by
the constructive genius of some one of the civilized nations. But
samples of the bricks out of which the great synthetic building
will have to be built, and even samples of some of its rooms, are
being prepared by the immense effort of the constructive genius of
man.
Second
Preface
Prince Peter Alexeivitch Kropotkin,
revolutionary and scientist, was descended from the old Russian
nobility, but decided, at the age of thirty, to throw in his lot
with the social rebels not only of his own country, but of the
entire world. He became the intellectual leader of
Anarchist-Communism; took part in the labor movement; wrote many
books and pamphlets; establishedLe
Révoltéin Geneva andFreedomin London; contributed to
theEncyclopedia Britannica;
was twice imprisoned because of his radical activities; and twice
visited America. After the Bolshevist revolution he returned to
Russia, kept himself apart from Soviet activities, and died true to
his ideals.The Conquest of Breadis a
revolutionary idyl, a beautiful outline sketch of a future society
based on liberty, equality and fraternity. It is, in Kropotkin's
own words, "a study of the needs of humanity, and of the economic
means to satisfy them." Read in conjunction with the same author's
"Fields, Factories and Workshops," it meets all the difficulties of
the social inquirer who says: "The Anarchist ideal is alluring, but
how could you work it out?"
CHAPTER I
OUR RICHESIThe human race has travelled a long way, since those remote
ages when men fashioned their rude implements of flint and lived on
the precarious spoils of hunting, leaving to their children for
their only heritage a shelter beneath the rocks, some poor
utensils—and Nature, vast, unknown, and terrific, with whom they
had to fight for their wretched existence.During the long succession of agitated ages which have
elapsed since, mankind has nevertheless amassed untold treasures.
It has cleared the land, dried the marshes, hewn down forests, made
roads, pierced mountains; it has been building, inventing,
observing, reasoning; it has created a complex machinery, wrested
her secrets from Nature, and finally it pressed steam and
electricity into its service. And the result is, that now the child
of the civilized man finds at its birth, ready for its use, an
immense capital accumulated by those who have gone before him. And
this capital enables man to acquire, merely by his own labour
combined with the labour of others, riches surpassing the dreams of
the fairy tales of the Thousand and One Nights.The soil is cleared to a great extent, fit for the reception
of the best seeds, ready to give a rich return for the skill and
labour spent upon it—a return more than sufficient for all the
wants of humanity. The methods of rational cultivation are
known.On the wide prairies of America each hundred men, with the
aid of powerful machinery, can produce in a few months enough wheat
to maintain ten thousand people for a whole year. And where man
wishes to double his produce, to treble it, to multiply it a
hundred-fold, hemakesthe soil,
gives to each plant the requisite care, and thus obtains enormous
returns. While the hunter of old had to scour fifty or sixty square
miles to find food for his family, the civilized man supports his
household, with far less pains, and far more certainty, on a
thousandth part of that space. Climate is no longer an obstacle.
When the sun fails, man replaces it by artificial heat; and we see
the coming of a time when artificial light also will be used to
stimulate vegetation. Meanwhile, by the use of glass and hot water
pipes, man renders a given space ten and fifty times more
productive than it was in its natural state.The prodigies accomplished in industry are still more
striking. With the co-operation of those intelligent beings, modern
machines—themselves the fruit of three or four generations of
inventors, mostly unknown—a hundred men manufacture now the stuff
to provide ten thousand persons with clothing for two years. In
well-managed coal mines the labour of a hundred miners furnishes
each year enough fuel to warm ten thousand families under an
inclement sky. And we have lately witnessed the spectacle of
wonderful cities springing up in a few months for international
exhibitions, without interrupting in the slightest degree the
regular work of the nations.And if in manufactures as in agriculture, and as indeed
through our whole social system, the labour, the discoveries, and
the inventions of our ancestors profit chiefly the few, it is none
the less certain that mankind in general, aided by the creatures of
steel and iron which it already possesses, could already procure an
existence of wealth and ease for every one of its
members.Truly, we are rich—far richer than we think; rich in what we
already possess, richer still in the possibilities of production of
our actual mechanical outfit; richest of all in what we might win
from our soil, from our manufactures, from our science, from our
technical knowledge, were they but applied to bringing about the
well-being of all.IIIn our civilized societies we are rich. Why then are the many
poor? Why this painful drudgery for the masses? Why, even to the
best paid workman, this uncertainty for the morrow, in the midst of
all the wealth inherited from the past, and in spite of the
powerful means of production, which could ensure comfort to all, in
return for a few hours of daily toil?The Socialists have said it and repeated it unwearyingly.
Daily they reiterate it, demonstrating it by arguments taken from
all the sciences. It is because all that is necessary for
production—the land, the mines, the highways, machinery, food,
shelter, education, knowledge—all have been seized by the few in
the course of that long story of robbery, enforced migration and
wars, of ignorance and oppression, which has been the life of the
human race before it had learned to subdue the forces of Nature. It
is because, taking advantage of alleged rights acquired in the
past, these few appropriate to-day two-thirds of the products of
human labour, and then squander them in the most stupid and
shameful way. It is because, having reduced the masses to a point
at which they have not the means of subsistence for a month, or
even for a week in advance, the few can allow the many to work,
only on the condition of themselves receiving the lion's share. It
is because these few prevent the remainder of men from producing
the things they need, and force them to produce, not the
necessaries of life for all, but whatever offers the greatest
profits to the monopolists. In this is the substance of all
Socialism.Take, indeed, a civilized country. The forests which once
covered it have been cleared, the marshes drained, the climate
improved. It has been made habitable. The soil, which bore formerly
only a coarse vegetation, is covered to-day with rich harvests. The
rock-walls in the valleys are laid out in terraces and covered with
vines. The wild plants, which yielded nought but acrid berries, or
uneatable roots, have been transformed by generations of culture
into succulent vegetables or trees covered with delicious fruits.
Thousands of highways and railroads furrow the earth, and pierce
the mountains. The shriek of the engine is heard in the wild gorges
of the Alps, the Caucasus, and the Himalayas. The rivers have been
made navigable; the coasts, carefully surveyed, are easy of access;
artificial harbours, laboriously dug out and protected against the
fury of the sea, afford shelter to the ships. Deep shafts have been
sunk in the rocks; labyrinths of underground galleries have been
dug out where coal may be raised or minerals extracted. At the
crossings of the highways great cities have sprung up, and within
their borders all the treasures of industry, science, and art have
been accumulated.Whole generations, that lived and died in misery, oppressed
and ill-treated by their masters, and worn out by toil, have handed
on this immense inheritance to our century.For thousands of years millions of men have laboured to clear
the forests, to drain the marshes, and to open up highways by land
and water. Every rood of soil we cultivate in Europe has been
watered by the sweat of several races of men. Every acre has its
story of enforced labour, of intolerable toil, of the people's
sufferings. Every mile of railway, every yard of tunnel, has
received its share of human blood.The shafts of the mine still bear on their rocky walls the
marks made by the pick of the workman who toiled to excavate them.
The space between each prop in the underground galleries might be
marked as a miner's grave; and who can tell what each of these
graves has cost, in tears, in privations, in unspeakable
wretchedness to the family who depended on the scanty wage of the
worker cut off in his prime by fire-damp, rock-fall, or
flood?The cities, bound together by railroads and waterways, are
organisms which have lived through centuries. Dig beneath them and
you find, one above another, the foundations of streets, of houses,
of theatres, of public buildings. Search into their history and you
will see how the civilization of the town, its industry, its
special characteristics, have slowly grown and ripened through the
co-operation of generations of its inhabitants before it could
become what it is to-day. And even to-day, the value of each
dwelling, factory, and warehouse, which has been created by the
accumulated labour of the millions of workers, now dead and buried,
is only maintained by the very presence and labour of legions of
the men who now inhabit that special corner of the globe. Each of
the atoms composing what we call the Wealth of Nations owes its
value to the fact that it is a part of the great whole. What would
a London dockyard or a great Paris warehouse be if they were not
situated in these great centres of international commerce? What
would become of our mines, our factories, our workshops, and our
railways, without the immense quantities of merchandise transported
every day by sea and land?Millions of human beings have laboured to create this
civilization on which we pride ourselves to-day. Other millions,
scattered through the globe, labour to maintain it. Without them
nothing would be left in fifty years but ruins.There is not even a thought, or an invention, which is not
common property, born of the past and the present. Thousands of
inventors, known and unknown, who have died in poverty, have
co-operated in the invention of each of these machines which embody
the genius of man.Thousands of writers, of poets, of scholars, have laboured to
increase knowledge, to dissipate error, and to create that
atmosphere of scientific thought, without which the marvels of our
century could never have appeared. And these thousands of
philosophers, of poets, of scholars, of inventors, have themselves
been supported by the labour of past centuries. They have been
upheld and nourished through life, both physically and mentally, by
legions of workers and craftsmen of all sorts. They have drawn
their motive force from the environment.The genius of a Séguin, a Mayer, a Grove, has certainly done
more to launch industry in new directions than all the capitalists
in the world. But men of genius are themselves the children of
industry as well as of science. Not until thousands of
steam-engines had been working for years before all eyes,
constantly transforming heat into dynamic force, and this force
into sound, light, and electricity, could the insight of genius
proclaim the mechanical origin and the unity of the physical
forces. And if we, children of the nineteenth century, have at last
grasped this idea, if we know now how to apply it, it is again
because daily experience has prepared the way. The thinkers of the
eighteenth century saw and declared it, but the idea remained
undeveloped, because the eighteenth century had not grown up like
ours, side by side with the steam-engine. Imagine the decades that
might have passed while we remained in ignorance of this law, which
has revolutionized modern industry, had Watt not found at Soho
skilled workmen to embody his ideas in metal, bringing all the
parts of his engine to perfection, so that steam, pent in a
complete mechanism, and rendered more docile than a horse, more
manageable than water, became at last the very soul of modern
industry.Every machine has had the same history—a long record of
sleepless nights and of poverty, of disillusions and of joys, of
partial improvements discovered by several generations of nameless
workers, who have added to the original invention these little
nothings, without which the most fertile idea would remain
fruitless. More than that: every new invention is a synthesis, the
resultant of innumerable inventions which have preceded it in the
vast field of mechanics and industry.Science and industry, knowledge and application, discovery
and practical realization leading to new discoveries, cunning of
brain and of hand, toil of mind and muscle—all work together. Each
discovery, each advance, each increase in the sum of human riches,
owes its being to the physical and mental travail of the past and
the present.By what right then can any one whatever appropriate the least
morsel of this immense whole and say—This is mine, not
yours?IIIIt has come about, however, in the course of the ages
traversed by the human race, that all that enables man to produce
and to increase his power of production has been seized by the few.
Some time, perhaps, we will relate how this came to pass. For the
present let it suffice to state the fact and analyze its
consequences.To-day the soil, which actually owes its value to the needs
of an ever-increasing population, belongs to a minority who prevent
the people from cultivating it—or do not allow them to cultivate it
according to modern methods.The mines, though they represent the labour of several
generations, and derive their sole value from the requirements of
the industry of a nation and the density of the population—the
mines also belong to the few; and these few restrict the output of
coal, or prevent it entirely, if they find more profitable
investments for their capital. Machinery, too, has become the
exclusive property of the few, and even when a machine
incontestably represents the improvements added to the original
rough invention by three or four generations of workers, it none
the less belongs to a few owners. And if the descendants of the
very inventor who constructed the first machine for lace-making, a
century ago, were to present themselves to-day in a lace factory at
Bâle or Nottingham, and claim their rights, they would be told:
"Hands off! this machine is not yours," and they would be shot down
if they attempted to take possession of it.The railways, which would be useless as so much old iron
without the teeming population of Europe, its industry, its
commerce, and its marts, belong to a few shareholders, ignorant
perhaps of the whereabouts of the lines of rails which yield them
revenues greater than those of medieval kings. And if the children
of those who perished by thousands while excavating the railway
cuttings and tunnels were to assemble one day, crowding in their
rags and hunger, to demand bread from the shareholders, they would
be met with bayonets and grapeshot, to disperse them and safeguard
"vested interests."In virtue of this monstrous system, the son of the worker, on
entering life, finds no field which he may till, no machine which
he may tend, no mine in which he may dig, without accepting to
leave a great part of what he will produce to a master. He must
sell his labour for a scant and uncertain wage. His father and his
grandfather have toiled to drain this field, to build this mill, to
perfect this machine. They gave to the work the full measure of
their strength, and what more could they give? But their heir comes
into the world poorer than the lowest savage. If he obtains leave
to till the fields, it is on condition of surrendering a quarter of
the produce to his master, and another quarter to the government
and the middlemen. And this tax, levied upon him by the State, the
capitalist, the lord of the manor, and the middleman, is always
increasing; it rarely leaves him the power to improve his system of
culture. If he turns to industry, he is allowed to work—though not
always even that—only on condition that he yield a half or
two-thirds of the product to him whom the land recognizes as the
owner of the machine.We cry shame on the feudal baron who forbade the peasant to
turn a clod of earth unless he surrendered to his lord a fourth of
his crop. We called those the barbarous times. But if the forms
have changed, the relations have remained the same, and the worker
is forced, under the name of free contract, to accept feudal
obligations. For, turn where he will, he can find no better
conditions. Everything has become private property, and he must
accept, or die of hunger.The result of this state of things is that all our production
tends in a wrong direction. Enterprise takes no thought for the
needs of the community. Its only aim is to increase the gains of
the speculator. Hence the constant fluctuations of trade, the
periodical industrial crises, each of which throws scores of
thousands of workers on the streets.The working people cannot purchase with their wages the
wealth which they have produced, and industry seeks foreign markets
among the monied classes of other nations. In the East, in Africa,
everywhere, in Egypt, Tonkin or the Congo, the European is thus
bound to promote the growth of serfdom. And so he does. But soon he
finds that everywhere there are similar competitors. All the
nations evolve on the same lines, and wars, perpetual wars, break
out for the right of precedence in the market. Wars for the
possession of the East, wars for the empire of the sea, wars to
impose duties on imports and to dictate conditions to neighbouring
states; wars against those "blacks" who revolt! The roar of the
cannon never ceases in the world, whole races are massacred, the
states of Europe spend a third of their budgets in armaments; and
we know how heavily these taxes fall on the workers.Education still remains the privilege of a small minority,
for it is idle to talk of education when the workman's child is
forced, at the age of thirteen, to go down into the mine or to help
his father on the farm. It is idle to talk of studying to the
worker, who comes home in the evening wearied by excessive toil,
and its brutalizing atmosphere. Society is thus bound to remain
divided into two hostile camps, and in such conditions freedom is a
vain word. The Radical begins by demanding a greater extension of
political rights, but he soon sees that the breath of liberty leads
to the uplifting of the proletariat, and then he turns round,
changes his opinions, and reverts to repressive legislation and
government by the sword.A vast array of courts, judges, executioners, policemen, and
gaolers is needed to uphold these privileges; and this array gives
rise in its turn to a whole system of espionage, of false witness,
of spies, of threats and corruption.The system under which we live checks in its turn the growth
of the social sentiment. We all know that without uprightness,
without self-respect, without sympathy and mutual aid, human kind
must perish, as perish the few races of animals living by rapine,
or the slave-keeping ants. But such ideas are not to the taste of
the ruling classes, and they have elaborated a whole system of
pseudo-science to teach the contrary.Fine sermons have been preached on the text that those who
have should share with those who have not, but he who would carry
out this principle would be speedily informed that these beautiful
sentiments are all very well in poetry, but not in practice. "To
lie is to degrade and besmirch oneself," we say, and yet all
civilized life becomes one huge lie. We accustom ourselves and our
children to hypocrisy, to the practice of a double-faced morality.
And since the brain is ill at ease among lies, we cheat ourselves
with sophistry. Hypocrisy and sophistry become the second nature of
the civilized man.But a society cannot live thus; it must return to truth, or
cease to exist.Thus the consequences which spring from the original act of
monopoly spread through the whole of social life. Under pain of
death, human societies are forced to return to first principles:
the means of production being the collective work of humanity, the
product should be the collective property of the race. Individual
appropriation is neither just nor serviceable. All belongs to all.
All things are for all men, since all men have need of them, since
all men have worked in the measure of their strength to produce
them, and since it is not possible to evaluate every one's part in
the production of the world's wealth.All things for all. Here is an immense stock of tools and
implements; here are all those iron slaves which we call machines,
which saw and plane, spin and weave for us, unmaking and remaking,
working up raw matter to produce the marvels of our time. But
nobody has the right to seize a single one of these machines and
say: "This is mine; if you want to use it you must pay me a tax on
each of your products," any more than the feudal lord of medieval
times had the right to say to the peasant: "This hill, this meadow
belong to me, and you must pay me a tax on every sheaf of corn you
reap, on every brick you build."All is for all! If the man and the woman bear their fair
share of work, they have a right to their fair share of all that is
produced by all, and that share is enough to secure them
well-being. No more of such vague formulas as "The right to work,"
or "To each the whole result of his labour." What we proclaim is
The Right to Well-Being: Well-Being for All!
CHAPTER II
WELL-BEING FOR ALL
I
Well-being for all is not a dream. It is possible,
realizable, owing to all that our ancestors have done to increase
our powers of production.
We know, indeed, that the producers, although they constitute
hardly one-third of the inhabitants of civilized countries, even
now produce such quantities of goods that a certain degree of
comfort could be brought to every hearth. We know further that if
all those who squander to-day the fruits of others' toil were
forced to employ their leisure in useful work, our wealth would
increase in proportion to the number of producers, and more.
Finally, we know that contrary to the theory enunciated by
Malthus—that Oracle of middle-class Economics—the productive powers
of the human race increase at a much more rapid ratio than its
powers of reproduction. The more thickly men are crowded on the
soil, the more rapid is the growth of their wealth-creating
power.
Thus, although the population of England has only increased
from 1844 to 1890 by 62 per cent., its production has grown, even
at the lowest estimate, at double that rate—to wit, by 130 per
cent. In France, where the population has grown more slowly, the
increase in production is nevertheless very rapid. Notwithstanding
the crises through which agriculture is frequently passing,
notwithstanding State interference, the blood-tax (conscription),
and speculative commerce and finance, the production of wheat in
France has increased four-fold, and industrial production more than
tenfold, in the course of the last eighty years. In the United
States this progress is still more striking. In spite of
immigration, or rather precisely because of the influx of surplus
European labour, the United States have multiplied their wealth
tenfold.
However, these figures give but a very faint idea of what our
wealth might become under better conditions. For alongside of the
rapid development of our wealth-producing powers we have an
overwhelming increase in the ranks of the idlers and middlemen.
Instead of capital gradually concentrating itself in a few hands,
so that it would only be necessary for the community to dispossess
a few millionaires and enter upon its lawful heritage—instead of
this Socialist forecast proving true, the exact reverse is coming
to pass: the swarm of parasites is ever increasing.
In France there are not ten actual producers to every thirty
inhabitants. The whole agricultural wealth of the country is the
work of less than seven millions of men, and in the two great
industries, mining and the textile trades, you will find that the
workers number less than two and one-half millions. But the
exploiters of labour, how many are they? In the United Kingdom a
little over one million workers—men, women, and children, are
employed in all the textile trades; less than nine hundred thousand
work the mines; much less than two million till the ground, and it
appeared from the last industrial census that only a little over
four million men, women and children were employed in all the
industries.[1]So that the statisticians have to exaggerate all the figures
in order to establish a maximum of eight million producers to
forty-five million inhabitants. Strictly speaking the creators of
the goods exported from Britain to all the ends of the earth
comprise only from six to seven million workers. And what is the
number of the shareholders and middlemen who levy the first fruits
of labour from far and near, and heap up unearned gains by
thrusting themselves between the producer and the consumer?
Nor is this all. The owners of capital constantly reduce the
output by restraining production. We need not speak of the
cartloads of oysters thrown into the sea to prevent a dainty,
hitherto reserved for the rich, from becoming a food for the
people. We need not speak of the thousand and one luxuries—stuffs,
foods, etc., etc.—treated after the same fashion as the oysters. It
is enough to remember the way in which the production of the most
necessary things is limited. Legions of miners are ready and
willing to dig out coal every day, and send it to those who are
shivering with cold; but too often a third, or even one-half, of
their number are forbidden to work more than three days a week,
because, forsooth, the price of coal must be kept up! Thousands of
weavers are forbidden to work the looms, although their wives and
children go in rags, and although three-quarters of the population
of Europe have no clothing worthy the name.
Hundreds of blast-furnaces, thousands of factories
periodically stand idle, others only work half-time—and in every
civilized nation there is a permanent population of about two
million individuals who ask only for work, but to whom work is
denied.
How gladly would these millions of men set to work to reclaim
waste lands, or to transform ill-cultivated land into fertile
fields, rich in harvests! A year of well-directed toil would
suffice to multiply fivefold the produce of those millions of acres
in this country which lie idle now as "permanent pasture," or of
those dry lands in the south of France which now yield only about
eight bushels of wheat per acre. But men, who would be happy to
become hardy pioneers in so many branches of wealth-producing
activity, must remain idle because the owners of the soil, the
mines and the factories prefer to invest their capital—taken in the
first place from the community—in Turkish or Egyptian bonds, or in
Patagonian gold mines, and so make Egyptian fellahs, Italian
emigrants, and Chinese coolies their wage-slaves.
This is the direct and deliberate limitation of production;
but there is also a limitation indirect and not of set purpose,
which consists in spending human toil on objects absolutely
useless, or destined only to satisfy the dull vanity of the
rich.
It is impossible to reckon in figures the extent to which
wealth is restricted indirectly, the extent to which energy is
squandered, while it might have served to produce, and above all to
prepare the machinery necessary to production. It is enough to cite
the immense sums spent by Europe in armaments, for the sole purpose
of acquiring control of markets, and so forcing her own goods on
neighbouring territories, and making exploitation easier at home;
the millions paid every year to officials of all sorts, whose
function it is to maintain the "rights" of minorities—the right,
that is, of a few rich men—to manipulate the economic activities of
the nation; the millions spent on judges, prisons, policemen, and
all the paraphernalia of so-called justice—spent to no purpose,
because we know that every alleviation, however slight, of the
wretchedness of our great cities is always followed by a
considerable diminution of crime; lastly, the millions spent on
propagating pernicious doctrines by means of the press, and news
"cooked" in the interest of this or that party, of this politician
or of that group of speculators.