Chapter II
Europe before the War
Before 1870 different parts of the small continent of Europe had
specialized in their own products; but, taken as a whole, it was
substantially self-subsistent. And its population was adjusted to
this state of affairs.
After 1870 there was developed on a large scale an unprecedented
situation, and the economic condition of Europe became during the
next fifty years unstable and peculiar. The pressure of population on
food, which had already been balanced by the accessibility of
supplies from America, became for the first time in recorded history
definitely reversed. As numbers increased, food was actually easier
to secure. Larger proportional returns from an increasing scale of
production became true of agriculture as well as industry. With the
growth of the European population there were more emigrants on the
one hand to till the soil of the new countries, and, on the other,
more workmen were available in Europe to prepare the industrial
products and capital goods which were to maintain the emigrant
populations in their new homes, and to build the railways and ships
which were to make accessible to Europe food and raw products from
distant sources. Up to about 1900 a unit of labor applied to industry
yielded year by year a purchasing power over an increasing quantity
of food. It is possible that about the year 1900 this process began
to be reversed, and a diminishing yield of Nature to man's effort was
beginning to reassert itself. But the tendency of cereals to rise in
real cost was balanced by other improvements; and—one of many
novelties—the resources of tropical Africa then for the first time
came into large employ, and a great traffic in oil-seeds began to
bring to the table of Europe in a new and cheaper form one of the
essential foodstuffs of mankind. In this economic Eldorado, in this
economic Utopia, as the earlier economists would have deemed it, most
of us were brought up.
That happy age lost sight of a view of the world which filled with
deep-seated melancholy the founders of our Political Economy. Before
the eighteenth century mankind entertained no false hopes. To lay the
illusions which grew popular at that age's latter end, Malthus
disclosed a Devil. For half a century all serious economical writings
held that Devil in clear prospect. For the next half century he was
chained up and out of sight. Now perhaps we have loosed him again.
What an extraordinary episode in the economic progress of man that
age was which came to an end in August, 1914! The greater part of the
population, it is true, worked hard and lived at a low standard of
comfort, yet were, to all appearances, reasonably contented with this
lot. But escape was possible, for any man of capacity or character at
all exceeding the average, into the middle and upper classes, for
whom life offered, at a low cost and with the least trouble,
conveniences, comforts, and amenities beyond the compass of the
richest and most powerful monarchs of other ages. The inhabitant of
London could order by telephone, sipping his morning tea in bed, the
various products of the whole earth, in such quantity as he might see
fit, and reasonably expect their early delivery upon his doorstep; he
could at the same moment and by the same means adventure his wealth
in the natural resources and new enterprises of any quarter of the
world, and share, without exertion or even trouble, in their
prospective fruits and advantages; or he could decide to couple the
security of his fortunes with the good faith of the townspeople of
any substantial municipality in any continent that fancy or
information might recommend. He could secure forthwith, if he wished
it, cheap and comfortable means of transit to any country or climate
without passport or other formality, could despatch his servant to
the neighboring office of a bank for such supply of the precious
metals as might seem convenient, and could then proceed abroad to
foreign quarters, without knowledge of their religion, language, or
customs, bearing coined wealth upon his person, and would consider
himself greatly aggrieved and much surprised at the least
interference. But, most important of all, he regarded this state of
affairs as normal, certain, and permanent, except in the direction of
further improvement, and any deviation from it as aberrant,
scandalous, and avoidable. The projects and politics of militarism
and imperialism, of racial and cultural rivalries, of monopolies,
restrictions, and exclusion, which were to play the serpent to this
paradise, were little more than the amusements of his daily
newspaper, and appeared to exercise almost no influence at all on the
ordinary course of social and economic life, the internationalization
of which was nearly complete in practice.
It will assist us to appreciate the character and consequences of
the Peace which we have imposed on our enemies, if I elucidate a
little further some of the chief unstable elements already present
when war broke out, in the economic life of Europe.I. Population
In 1870 Germany had a population of
about 40,000,000. By 1892 this figure had risen to 50,000,000, and by
June 30, 1914, to about 68,000,000. In the years immediately
preceding the war the annual increase was about 850,000, of whom an
insignificant proportion emigrated.[1] This great increase was
only rendered possible by a far-reaching transformation of the
economic structure of the country. From being agricultural and mainly
self-supporting, Germany transformed herself into a vast and
complicated industrial machine, dependent for its working on the
equipoise of many factors outside Germany as well as within. Only by
operating this machine, continuously and at full blast, could she
find occupation at home for her increasing population and the means
of purchasing their subsistence from abroad. The German machine was
like a top which to maintain its equilibrium must spin ever faster
and faster.
In the Austro-Hungarian Empire, which grew from about 40,000,000
in 1890 to at least 50,000,000 at the outbreak of war, the same
tendency was present in a less degree, the annual excess of births
over deaths being about half a million, out of which, however, there
was an annual emigration of some quarter of a million persons.To understand the present situation, we
must apprehend with vividness what an extraordinary center of
population the development of the Germanic system had enabled Central
Europe to become. Before the war the population of Germany and
Austria-Hungary together not only substantially exceeded that of the
United States, but was about equal to that of the whole of North
America. In these numbers, situated within a compact territory, lay
the military strength of the Central Powers. But these same
numbers—for even the war has not appreciably diminished them[2]—if
deprived of the means of life, remain a hardly less danger to
European order.European Russia increased her
population in a degree even greater than Germany—from less than
100,000,000 in 1890 to about 150,000,000 at the outbreak of
war;[3]and in the year immediately preceding 1914 the excess of
births over deaths in Russia as a whole was at the prodigious rate of
two millions per annum. This inordinate growth in the population of
Russia, which has not been widely noticed in England, has been
nevertheless one of the most significant facts of recent years.
The great events of history are often due to secular changes in
the growth of population and other fundamental economic causes,
which, escaping by their gradual character the notice of contemporary
observers, are attributed to the follies of statesmen or the
fanaticism of atheists. Thus the extraordinary occurrences of the
past two years in Russia, that vast upheaval of Society, which has
overturned what seemed most stable—religion, the basis of property,
the ownership of land, as well as forms of government and the
hierarchy of classes—may owe more to the deep influences of
expanding numbers than to Lenin or to Nicholas; and the disruptive
powers of excessive national fecundity may have played a greater part
in bursting the bonds of convention than either the power of ideas or
the errors of autocracy.II. Organization
The delicate organization by which these peoples lived depended
partly on factors internal to the system.
The interference of frontiers and of tariffs was reduced to a
minimum, and not far short of three hundred millions of people lived
within the three Empires of Russia, Germany, and Austria-Hungary. The
various currencies, which were all maintained on a stable basis in
relation to gold and to one another, facilitated the easy flow of
capital and of trade to an extent the full value of which we only
realize now, when we are deprived of its advantages. Over this great
area there was an almost absolute security of property and of person.
These factors of order, security, and uniformity, which Europe had
never before enjoyed over so wide and populous a territory or for so
long a period, prepared the way for the organization of that vast
mechanism of transport, coal distribution, and foreign trade which
made possible an industrial order of life in the dense urban centers
of new population. This is too well known to require detailed
substantiation with figures. But it may be illustrated by the figures
for coal, which has been the key to the industrial growth of Central
Europe hardly less than of England; the output of German coal grew
from 30,000,000 tons in 1871 to 70,000,000 tons in 1890, 110,000,000
tons in 1900, and 190,000,000 tons in 1913.
Round Germany as a central support the rest of the European
economic system grouped itself, and on the prosperity and enterprise
of Germany the prosperity of the rest of the Continent mainly
depended. The increasing pace of Germany gave her neighbors an outlet
for their products, in exchange for which the enterprise of the
German merchant supplied them with their chief requirements at a low
price.
The statistics of the economic interdependence of Germany and her
neighbors are overwhelming. Germany was the best customer of Russia,
Norway, Holland, Belgium, Switzerland, Italy, and Austria-Hungary;
she was the second best customer of Great Britain, Sweden, and
Denmark; and the third best customer of France. She was the largest
source of supply to Russia, Norway, Sweden, Denmark, Holland,
Switzerland, Italy, Austria-Hungary, Roumania, and Bulgaria; and the
second largest source of supply to Great Britain, Belgium, and
France.
In our own case we sent more exports to Germany than to any other
country in the world except India, and we bought more from her than
from any other country in the world except the United States.
There was no European country except those west of Germany which
did not do more than a quarter of their total trade with her; and in
the case of Russia, Austria-Hungary, and Holland the proportion was
far greater.Germany not only furnished these
countries with trade, but, in the case of some of them, supplied a
great part of the capital needed for their own development. Of
Germany's pre-war foreign investments, amounting in all to about
$6,250,000,000, not far short of $2,500,000,000 was invested in
Russia, Austria-Hungary, Bulgaria, Roumania, and Turkey.[4] And
by the system of "peaceful penetration" she gave these
countries not only capital, but, what they needed hardly less,
organization. The whole of Europe east of the Rhine thus fell into
the German industrial orbit, and its economic life was adjusted
accordingly.
But these internal factors would not have been sufficient to
enable the population to support itself without the co-operation of
external factors also and of certain general dispositions common to
the whole of Europe. Many of the circumstances already treated were
true of Europe as a whole, and were not peculiar to the Central
Empires. But all of what follows was common to the whole European
system.III. The Psychology of Society
Europe was so organized socially and economically as to secure the
maximum accumulation of capital. While there was some continuous
improvement in the daily conditions of life of the mass of the
population, Society was so framed as to throw a great part of the
increased income into the control of the class least likely to
consume it. The new rich of the nineteenth century were not brought
up to large expenditures, and preferred the power which investment
gave them to the pleasures of immediate consumption. In fact, it was
precisely the inequality of the distribution of wealth
which made possible those vast accumulations of fixed wealth and of
capital improvements which distinguished that age from all others.
Herein lay, in fact, the main justification of the Capitalist System.
If the rich had spent their new wealth on their own enjoyments, the
world would long ago have found such a régime intolerable. But like
bees they saved and accumulated, not less to the advantage of the
whole community because they themselves held narrower ends in
prospect.
The immense accumulations of fixed capital which, to the great
benefit of mankind, were built up during the half century before the
war, could never have come about in a Society where wealth was
divided equitably. The railways of the world, which that age built as
a monument to posterity, were, not less than the Pyramids of Egypt,
the work of labor which was not free to consume in immediate
enjoyment the full equivalent of its efforts.
Thus this remarkable system depended for its growth on a double
bluff or deception. On the one hand the laboring classes accepted
from ignorance or powerlessness, or were compelled, persuaded, or
cajoled by custom, convention, authority, and the well-established
order of Society into accepting, a situation in which they could call
their own very little of the cake that they and Nature and the
capitalists were co-operating to produce. And on the other hand the
capitalist classes were allowed to call the best part of the cake
theirs and were theoretically free to consume it, on the tacit
underlying condition that they consumed very little of it in
practice. The duty of "saving" became nine-tenths of virtue
and the growth of the cake the object of true religion. There grew
round the non-consumption of the cake all those instincts of
puritanism which in other ages has withdrawn itself from the world
and has neglected the arts of production as well as those of
enjoyment. And so the cake increased; but to what end was not clearly
contemplated. Individuals would be exhorted not so much to abstain as
to defer, and to cultivate the pleasures of security and
anticipation. Saving was for old age or for your children; but this
was only in theory,—the virtue of the cake was that it was never to
be consumed, neither by you nor by your children after you.
In writing thus I do not necessarily disparage the practices of
that generation. In the unconscious recesses of its being Society
knew what it was about. The cake was really very small in proportion
to the appetites of consumption, and no one, if it were shared all
round, would be much the better off by the cutting of it. Society was
working not for the small pleasures of to-day but for the future
security and improvement of the race,—in fact for "progress."
If only the cake were not cut but was allowed to grow in the
geometrical proportion predicted by Malthus of population, but not
less true of compound interest, perhaps a day might come when there
would at last be enough to go round, and when posterity could enter
into the enjoyment of our labors. In that day overwork,
overcrowding, and underfeeding would have come to an end, and men,
secure of the comforts and necessities of the body, could proceed to
the nobler exercises of their faculties. One geometrical ratio might
cancel another, and the nineteenth century was able to forget the
fertility of the species in a contemplation of the dizzy virtues of
compound interest.
There were two pitfalls in this prospect: lest, population still
outstripping accumulation, our self-denials promote not happiness but
numbers; and lest the cake be after all consumed, prematurely, in
war, the consumer of all such hopes.
But these thoughts lead too far from my present purpose. I seek
only to point out that the principle of accumulation based on
inequality was a vital part of the pre-war order of Society and of
progress as we then understood it, and to emphasize that this
principle depended on unstable psychological conditions, which it may
be impossible to recreate. It was not natural for a population, of
whom so few enjoyed the comforts of life, to accumulate so hugely.
The war has disclosed the possibility of consumption to all and the
vanity of abstinence to many. Thus the bluff is discovered; the
laboring classes may be no longer willing to forego so largely, and
the capitalist classes, no longer confident of the future, may seek
to enjoy more fully their liberties of consumption so long as they
last, and thus precipitate the hour of their confiscation.IV. The Relation of the Old World to the New
The accumulative habits of Europe before the war were the
necessary condition of the greatest of the external factors which
maintained the European equipoise.
Of the surplus capital goods accumulated by Europe a substantial
part was exported abroad, where its investment made possible the
development of the new resources of food, materials, and transport,
and at the same time enabled the Old World to stake out a claim in
the natural wealth and virgin potentialities of the New. This last
factor came to be of the vastest importance. The Old World employed
with an immense prudence the annual tribute it was thus entitled to
draw. The benefit of cheap and abundant supplies resulting from the
new developments which its surplus capital had made possible, was, it
is true, enjoyed and not postponed. But the greater part of the money
interest accruing on these foreign investments was reinvested and
allowed to accumulate, as a reserve (it was then hoped) against the
less happy day when the industrial labor of Europe could no longer
purchase on such easy terms the produce of other continents, and when
the due balance would be threatened between its historical
civilizations and the multiplying races of other climates and
environments. Thus the whole of the European races tended to benefit
alike from the development of new resources whether they pursued
their culture at home or adventured it abroad.
Even before the war, however, the equilibrium thus established
between old civilizations and new resources was being threatened. The
prosperity of Europe was based on the facts that, owing to the large
exportable surplus of foodstuffs in America, she was able to purchase
food at a cheap rate measured in terms of the labor required to
produce her own exports, and that, as a result of her previous
investments of capital, she was entitled to a substantial amount
annually without any payment in return at all. The second of these
factors then seemed out of danger, but, as a result of the growth of
population overseas, chiefly in the United States, the first was not
so secure.When first the virgin soils of America
came into bearing, the proportions of the population of those
continents themselves, and consequently of their own local
requirements, to those of Europe were very small. As lately as 1890
Europe had a population three times that of North and South America
added together. But by 1914 the domestic requirements of the United
States for wheat were approaching their production, and the date was
evidently near when there would be an exportable surplus only in
years of exceptionally favorable harvest. Indeed, the present
domestic requirements of the United States are estimated at more than
ninety per cent of the average yield of the five years
1909-1913.[5] At that time, however, the tendency towards
stringency was showing itself, not so much in a lack of abundance as
in a steady increase of real cost. That is to say, taking the world
as a whole, there was no deficiency of wheat, but in order to call
forth an adequate supply it was necessary to offer a higher real
price. The most favorable factor in the situation was to be found in
the extent to which Central and Western Europe was being fed from the
exportable surplus of Russia and Roumania.
In short, Europe's claim on the resources of the New World was
becoming precarious; the law of diminishing returns was at last
reasserting itself and was making it necessary year by year for
Europe to offer a greater quantity of other commodities to obtain the
same amount of bread; and Europe, therefore, could by no means afford
the disorganization of any of her principal sources of supply.
Much else might be said in an attempt to portray the economic
peculiarities of the Europe of 1914. I have selected for emphasis the
three or four greatest factors of instability,—the instability of
an excessive population dependent for its livelihood on a complicated
and artificial organization, the psychological instability of the
laboring and capitalist classes, and the instability of Europe's
claim, coupled with the completeness of her dependence, on the food
supplies of the New World.
The war had so shaken this system as to endanger the life of
Europe altogether. A great part of the Continent was sick and dying;
its population was greatly in excess of the numbers for which a
livelihood was available; its organization was destroyed, its
transport system ruptured, and its food supplies terribly impaired.
It was the task of the Peace Conference to honor engagements and
to satisfy justice; but not less to re-establish life and to heal
wounds. These tasks were dictated as much by prudence as by the
magnanimity which the wisdom of antiquity approved in victors. We
will examine in the following chapters the actual character of the
Peace.FOOTNOTES:
[1]In 1913 there were 25,843 emigrants
from Germany, of whom 19,124 went to the United States.[2]The net decrease of the German
population at the end of 1918 by decline of births and excess of
deaths as compared with the beginning of 1914, is estimated at about
2,700,000.[3]Including Poland and Finland, but
excluding Siberia, Central Asia, and the Caucasus.[4]Sums of money mentioned in this book
in terms of dollars have been converted from pounds sterling at the
rate of $5 to £1.[5]Even since 1914 the population of
the United States has increased by seven or eight millions. As their
annual consumption of wheat per head is not less than 6 bushels, the
pre-war scale of production in the United States would only show a
substantial surplus over present domestic requirements in about one
year out of five. We have been saved for the moment by the great
harvests of 1918 and 1919, which have been called forth by Mr.
Hoover's guaranteed price. But the United States can hardly be
expected to continue indefinitely to raise by a substantial figure
the cost of living in its own country, in order to provide wheat for
a Europe which cannot pay for it.Chapter III
The Conference
In Chapters IV. and V. I shall
study in some detail the economic and financial provisions of the
Treaty of Peace with Germany. But it will be easier to appreciate
the true origin of many of these terms if we examine here some of
the personal factors which influenced their preparation. In
attempting this task, I touch, inevitably, questions of motive, on
which spectators are liable to error and are not entitled to take
on themselves the responsibilities of final judgment. Yet, if I
seem in this chapter to assume sometimes the liberties which are
habitual to historians, but which, in spite of the greater
knowledge with which we speak, we generally hesitate to assume
towards contemporaries, let the reader excuse me when he remembers
how greatly, if it is to understand its destiny, the world needs
light, even if it is partial and uncertain, on the complex struggle
of human will and purpose, not yet finished, which, concentrated in
the persons of four individuals in a manner never paralleled, made
them, in the first months of 1919, the microcosm of mankind.
In those parts of the Treaty with which I am here concerned, the
lead was taken by the French, in the sense that it was generally
they who made in the first instance the most definite and the most
extreme proposals. This was partly a matter of tactics. When the
final result is expected to be a compromise, it is often prudent to
start from an extreme position; and the French anticipated at the
outset—like most other persons—a double process of compromise,
first of all to suit the ideas of their allies and associates, and
secondly in the course of the Peace Conference proper with the
Germans themselves. These tactics were justified by the event.
Clemenceau gained a reputation for moderation with his colleagues
in Council by sometimes throwing over with an air of intellectual
impartiality the more extreme proposals of his ministers; and much
went through where the American and British critics were naturally
a little ignorant of the true point at issue, or where too
persistent criticism by France's allies put them in a position
which they felt as invidious, of always appearing to take the
enemy's part and to argue his case. Where, therefore, British and
American interests were not seriously involved their criticism grew
slack, and some provisions were thus passed which the French
themselves did not take very seriously, and for which the
eleventh-hour decision to allow no discussion with the Germans
removed the opportunity of remedy.
But, apart from tactics, the French had a policy. Although
Clemenceau might curtly abandon the claims of a Klotz or a
Loucheur, or close his eyes with an air of fatigue when French
interests were no longer involved in the discussion, he knew which
points were vital, and these he abated little. In so far as the
main economic lines of the Treaty represent an intellectual idea,
it is the idea of France and of Clemenceau.
Clemenceau was by far the most eminent member of the Council of
Four, and he had taken the measure of his colleagues. He alone both
had an idea and had considered it in all its consequences. His age,
his character, his wit, and his appearance joined to give him
objectivity and a, defined outline in an environment of confusion.
One could not despise Clemenceau or dislike him, but only take a
different view as to the nature of civilized man, or indulge, at
least, a different hope.
The figure and bearing of Clemenceau are universally familiar.
At the Council of Four he wore a square-tailed coat of very good,
thick black broadcloth, and on his hands, which were never
uncovered, gray suede gloves; his boots were of thick black
leather, very good, but of a country style, and sometimes fastened
in front, curiously, by a buckle instead of laces. His seat in the
room in the President's house, where the regular meetings of the
Council of Four were held (as distinguished from their private and
unattended conferences in a smaller chamber below), was on a square
brocaded chair in the middle of the semicircle facing the
fireplace, with Signor Orlando on his left, the President next by
the fireplace, and the Prime Minister opposite on the other side of
the fireplace on his right. He carried no papers and no portfolio,
and was unattended by any personal secretary, though several French
ministers and officials appropriate to the particular matter in
hand would be present round him. His walk, his hand, and his voice
were not lacking in vigor, but he bore nevertheless, especially
after the attempt upon him, the aspect of a very old man conserving
his strength for important occasions. He spoke seldom, leaving the
initial statement of the French case to his ministers or officials;
he closed his eyes often and sat back in his chair with an
impassive face of parchment, his gray gloved hands clasped in front
of him. A short sentence, decisive or cynical, was generally
sufficient, a question, an unqualified abandonment of his
ministers, whose face would not be saved, or a display of obstinacy
reinforced by a few words in a piquantly delivered English.[6] But
speech and passion were not lacking when they were wanted, and the
sudden outburst of words, often followed by a fit of deep coughing
from the chest, produced their impression rather by force and
surprise than by persuasion.
Not infrequently Mr. Lloyd George, after delivering a speech in
English, would, during the period of its interpretation into
French, cross the hearthrug to the President to reinforce his case
by some ad hominem argument in private conversation, or to sound
the ground for a compromise,—and this would sometimes be the signal
for a general upheaval and disorder. The President's advisers would
press round him, a moment later the British experts would dribble
across to learn the result or see that all was well, and next the
French would be there, a little suspicious lest the others were
arranging something behind them, until all the room were on their
feet and conversation was general in both languages. My last and
most vivid impression is of such a scene—the President and the
Prime Minister as the center of a surging mob and a babel of sound,
a welter of eager, impromptu compromises and counter-compromises,
all sound and fury signifying nothing, on what was an unreal
question anyhow, the great issues of the morning's meeting
forgotten and neglected; and Clemenceau silent and aloof on the
outskirts—for nothing which touched the security of France was
forward—throned, in his gray gloves, on the brocade chair, dry in
soul and empty of hope, very old and tired, but surveying the scene
with a cynical and almost impish air; and when at last silence was
restored and the company had returned to their places, it was to
discover that he had disappeared.
He felt about France what Pericles felt of Athens—unique value
in her, nothing else mattering; but his theory of politics was
Bismarck's. He had one illusion—France; and one
disillusion—mankind, including Frenchmen, and his colleagues not
least. His principles for the peace can be expressed simply. In the
first place, he was a foremost believer in the view of German
psychology that the German understands and can understand nothing
but intimidation, that he is without generosity or remorse in
negotiation, that there is no advantage he will not take of you,
and no extent to which he will not demean himself for profit, that
he is without honor, pride, or mercy. Therefore you must never
negotiate with a German or conciliate him; you must dictate to him.
On no other terms will he respect you, or will you prevent him from
cheating you. But it is doubtful how far he thought these
characteristics peculiar to Germany, or whether his candid view of
some other nations was fundamentally different. His philosophy had,
therefore, no place for "sentimentality" in international
relations. Nations are real things, of whom you love one and feel
for the rest indifference—or hatred. The glory of the nation you
love is a desirable end,—but generally to be obtained at your
neighbor's expense. The politics of power are inevitable, and there
is nothing very new to learn about this war or the end it was
fought for; England had destroyed, as in each preceding century, a
trade rival; a mighty chapter had been closed in the secular
struggle between the glories of Germany and of France. Prudence
required some measure of lip service to the "ideals" of foolish
Americans and hypocritical Englishmen; but it would be stupid to
believe that there is much room in the world, as it really is, for
such affairs as the League of Nations, or any sense in the
principle of self-determination except as an ingenious formula for
rearranging the balance of power in one's own interests.
These, however, are generalities. In tracing the practical
details of the Peace which he thought necessary for the power and
the security of France, we must go back to the historical causes
which had operated during his lifetime. Before the Franco-German
war the populations of France and Germany were approximately equal;
but the coal and iron and shipping of Germany were in their
infancy, and the wealth of France was greatly superior. Even after
the loss of Alsace-Lorraine there was no great discrepancy between
the real resources of the two countries. But in the intervening
period the relative position had changed completely. By 1914 the
population of Germany was nearly seventy per cent in excess of that
of France; she had become one of the first manufacturing and
trading nations of the world; her technical skill and her means for
the production of future wealth were unequaled. France on the other
hand had a stationary or declining population, and, relatively to
others, had fallen seriously behind in wealth and in the power to
produce it.
In spite, therefore, of France's victorious issue from the
present struggle (with the aid, this time, of England and America),
her future position remained precarious in the eyes of one who took
the view that European civil war is to be regarded as a normal, or
at least a recurrent, state of affairs for the future, and that the
sort of conflicts between organized great powers which have
occupied the past hundred years will also engage the next.
According to this vision of the future, European history is to be a
perpetual prize-fight, of which France has won this round, but of
which this round is certainly not the last. From the belief that
essentially the old order does not change, being based on human
nature which is always the same, and from a consequent skepticism
of all that class of doctrine which the League of Nations stands
for, the policy of France and of Clemenceau followed logically. For
a Peace of magnanimity or of fair and equal treatment, based on
such "ideology" as the Fourteen Points of the President, could only
have the effect of shortening the interval of Germany's recovery
and hastening the day when she will once again hurl at France her
greater numbers and her superior resources and technical skill.
Hence the necessity of "guarantees"; and each guarantee that was
taken, by increasing irritation and thus the probability of a
subsequent Revanche by Germany, made necessary yet further
provisions to crush. Thus, as soon as this view of the world is
adopted and the other discarded, a demand for a Carthaginian Peace
is inevitable, to the full extent of the momentary power to impose
it. For Clemenceau made no pretense of considering himself bound by
the Fourteen Points and left chiefly to others such concoctions as
were necessary from time to time to save the scruples or the face
of the President.
So far as possible, therefore, it was the policy of France to
set the clock back and to undo what, since 1870, the progress of
Germany had accomplished. By loss of territory and other measures
her population was to be curtailed; but chiefly the economic
system, upon which she depended for her new strength, the vast
fabric built upon iron, coal, and transport must be destroyed. If
France could seize, even in part, what Germany was compelled to
drop, the inequality of strength between the two rivals for
European hegemony might be remedied for many generations.
Hence sprang those cumulative provisions for the destruction of
highly organized economic life which we shall examine in the next
chapter.
This is the policy of an old man, whose most vivid impressions
and most lively imagination are of the past and not of the future.
He sees the issue in terms, of France and Germany not of humanity
and of European civilization struggling forwards to a new order.
The war has bitten into his consciousness somewhat differently from
ours, and he neither expects nor hopes that we are at the threshold
of a new age.
It happens, however, that it is not only an ideal question that
is at issue. My purpose in this book is to show that the
Carthaginian Peace is not practically right or possible. Although
the school of thought from which it springs is aware of the
economic factor, it overlooks, nevertheless, the deeper economic
tendencies which are to govern the future. The clock cannot be set
back. You cannot restore Central Europe to 1870 without setting up
such strains in the European structure and letting loose such human
and spiritual forces as, pushing beyond frontiers and races, will
overwhelm not only you and your "guarantees," but your
institutions, and the existing order of your Society.
By what legerdemain was this policy substituted for the Fourteen
Points, and how did the President come to accept it? The answer to
these questions is difficult and depends on elements of character
and psychology and on the subtle influence of surroundings, which
are hard to detect and harder still to describe. But, if ever the
action of a single individual matters, the collapse of The
President has been one of the decisive moral events of history; and
I must make an attempt to explain it. What a place the President
held in the hearts and hopes of the world when he sailed to us in
the George Washington! What [...]