The Condition of the Working-Class in England in 1844
The Condition of the Working-Class in England in 1844PREFACEINTRODUCTIONTHE INDUSTRIAL PROLETARIAT.THE GREAT TOWNS.COMPETITION.IRISH IMMIGRATION.RESULTS.SINGLE BRANCHES OF INDUSTRY. FACTORY HANDS.THE REMAINING BRANCHES OF INDUSTRY.LABOUR MOVEMENTS.THE AGRICULTURAL PROLETARIAT.THE ATTITUDE OF THE BOURGEOISIE TOWARDS THE PROLETARIAT.Copyright
The Condition of the Working-Class in England in 1844
Frederick Engels
PREFACE
The book, an English translation of which is here republished, was
first issued in Germany in 1845. The author, at that time, was
young, twenty-four years of age, and his production bears the stamp
of his youth with its good and its faulty features, of neither of
which he feels ashamed. It was translated into English, in 1885, by
an American lady, Mrs. F. Kelley Wischnewetzky, and published in
the following year in New York. The American edition being as good
as exhausted, and having never been extensively circulated on this
side of the Atlantic, the present English copyright edition is
brought out with the full consent of all parties interested.
For the American edition, a new Preface and an Appendix were
written in English by the author. The first had little to do with
the book itself; it discussed the American Working-Class Movement
of the day, and is, therefore, here omitted as irrelevant, the
second—the original preface—is largely made use of in the present
introductory remarks.
The state of things described in this book belongs to-day, in many
respects, to the past, as far as England is concerned. Though not
expressly stated in our recognised treatises, it is still a law of
modern Political Economy that the larger the scale on which
Capitalistic Production is carried on, the less can it support the
petty devices of swindling and pilfering which characterise its
early stages. The pettifogging business tricks of the Polish Jew,
the representative in Europe of commerce in its lowest stage, those
tricks that serve him so well in his own country, and are generally
practised there, he finds to be out of date and out of place when
he comes to Hamburg or Berlin; and, again, the commission p.
viagent, who hails from Berlin or Hamburg, Jew or Christian, after
frequenting the Manchester Exchange for a few months, finds out
that, in order to buy cotton yarn or cloth cheap, he, too, had
better drop those slightly more refined but still miserable wiles
and subterfuges which are considered the acme of cleverness in his
native country. The fact is, those tricks do not pay any longer in
a large market, where time is money, and where a certain standard
of commercial morality is unavoidably developed, purely as a means
of saving time and trouble. And it is the same with the relation
between the manufacturer and his “hands.”
The revival of trade, after the crisis of 1847, was the dawn of a
new industrial epoch. The repeal of the Corn Laws and the financial
reforms subsequent thereon gave to English industry and commerce
all the elbow-room they had asked for. The discovery of the
Californian and Australian gold-fields followed in rapid
succession. The Colonial markets developed at an increasing rate
their capacity for absorbing English manufactured goods. In India
millions of hand-weavers were finally crushed out by the Lancashire
power-loom. China was more and more being opened up. Above all, the
United States—then, commercially speaking, a mere colonial market,
but by far the biggest of them all—underwent an economic
development astounding even for that rapidly progressive country.
And, finally, the new means of communication introduced at the
close of the preceding period—railways and ocean steamers—were now
worked out on an international scale; they realised actually, what
had hitherto existed only potentially, a world-market. This
world-market, at first, was composed of a number of chiefly or
entirely agricultural countries grouped around one manufacturing
centre—England—which consumed the greater part of their surplus raw
produce, and supplied them in return with the greater part of their
requirements in manufactured articles. No wonder England’s
industrial progress was colossal and unparalleled, and such that
the status of 1844 now appears to us as comparatively primitive and
insignificant. And in proportion as this increase took place, in
the same proportion did manufacturing industry become apparently
moralised. The competition of manufacturer against manufacturer by
means of petty thefts upon the workpeople did no longer pay. Trade
had outgrown such low means of making money; they were not worth
while practising for the manufacturing millionaire, and served
merely to keep alive the competition of smaller traders, thankful
to pick up a penny wherever they could. Thus the truck system was
suppressed, the Ten Hours’ Bill was enacted, and a number of other
secondary reforms introduced—much against the spirit of Free Trade
and unbridled competition, but quite as much in favour of the
giant-capitalist in his competition with his less favoured brother.
Moreover, the larger the concern, and with it the number of hands,
the greater the loss and inconvenience caused by every conflict
between master and men; and thus a new spirit came over the
masters, especially the large ones, which taught them to avoid
unnecessary squabbles, to acquiesce in the existence and power of
Trades’ Unions, and finally even to discover in strikes—at
opportune times—a powerful means to serve their own ends. The
largest manufacturers, formerly the leaders of the war against the
working-class, were now the foremost to preach peace and harmony.
And for a very good reason. The fact is, that all these concessions
to justice and philanthropy were nothing else but means to
accelerate the concentration of capital in the hands of the few,
for whom the niggardly extra extortions of former years had lost
all importance and had become actual nuisances; and to crush all
the quicker and all the safer their smaller competitors, who could
not make both ends meet without such perquisites. Thus the
development of production on the basis of the capitalistic system
has of itself sufficed—at least in the leading industries, for in
the more unimportant branches this is far from being the case—to do
away with all those minor grievances which aggravated the workman’s
fate during its earlier stages. And thus it renders more and more
evident the great central fact, that the cause of the miserable
condition of the working-class is to be sought, not in these minor
grievances, but in the Capitalistic System itself. The wage-worker
sells to the capitalist his labour-force for a certain daily sum.
After a few hours’ work he has reproduced the value of that sum;
but the substance of his contract is, that he has to work another
series of hours to complete his working-day; and the value he
produces during these additional hours of surplus labour is surplus
value, which cost the capitalist nothing, but yet goes into his
pocket. That is the basis of the system which tends more and more
to split up civilised society into a few Rothschilds and
Vanderbilts, the owners of all the means of production and
subsistence, on the one hand, and an immense number of
wage-workers, the owners of nothing but their labour-force, on the
other. And that this result is caused, not by this or that
secondary grievance, but by the system itself—this fact has been
brought out in bold relief by the development of Capitalism in
England since 1847.
Again, the repeated visitations of cholera, typhus, smallpox, and
other epidemics have shown the British bourgeois the urgent
necessity of sanitation in his towns and cities, if he wishes to
save himself and family from falling victims to such diseases.
Accordingly, the most crying abuses described in this book have
either disappeared or have been made less conspicuous. Drainage has
been introduced or improved, wide avenues have been opened out
athwart many of the worst “slums” I had to describe. “Little
Ireland” has disappeared, and the “Seven Dials” are next on the
list for sweeping away. But what of that? Whole districts which in
1844 I could describe as almost idyllic, have now, with the growth
of the towns, fallen into the same state of dilapidation,
discomfort, and misery. Only the pigs and the heaps of refuse are
no longer tolerated. The bourgeoisie have made further progress in
the art of hiding the distress of the working-class. But that, in
regard to their dwellings, no substantial improvement has taken
place, is amply proved by the Report of the Royal Commission “on
the Housing of the Poor,” 1885. And this is the case, too, in other
respects. Police regulations have been plentiful as blackberries;
but they can only hedge in the distress of the workers, they cannot
remove it.
But while England has thus outgrown the juvenile state of
capitalist exploitation described by me, other countries have only
just attained it. France, Germany, and especially America, are the
formidable competitors who, at this moment—as foreseen by me in
1844—are more and more breaking up England’s industrial monopoly.
Their manufactures are young as compared with those of England, but
increasing at a far more rapid rate than the latter; and, curious
enough, they have at this moment arrived at about the same phase of
development as English manufacture in 1844. With regard to America,
the parallel is indeed most striking. True, the external
surroundings in which the working-class is placed in America are
very different, but the same economical laws are at work, and the
results, if not identical in every respect, must still be of the
same order. Hence we find in America the same struggles for a
shorter working-day, for a legal limitation of the working-time,
especially of women and children in factories; we find the
truck-system in full blossom, and the cottage-system, in rural
districts, made use of by the “bosses” as a means of domination
over the workers. When I received, in 1886, the American papers
with accounts of the great strike of 12,000 Pennsylvanian
coal-miners in the Connellsville district, I seemed but to read my
own description of the North of England colliers’ strike of 1844.
The same cheating of the workpeople by false measure; the same
truck-system; the same attempt to break the miners’ resistance by
the capitalists’ last, but crushing, resource,—the eviction of the
men out of their dwellings, the cottages owned by the
companies.
I have not attempted, in this translation, to bring the book up to
date, or to point out in detail all the changes that have taken
place since 1844. And for two reasons: Firstly, to do this
properly, the size of the book must be about doubled; and,
secondly, the first volume of “Das Kapital,” by Karl Marx, an
English translation of which is before the public, contains a very
ample description of the state of the British working-class, as it
was about 1865, that is to say, at the time when British industrial
prosperity reached its culminating point. I should, then, have been
obliged again to go over the ground already covered by Marx’s
celebrated work.
It will be hardly necessary to point out that the general
theoretical standpoint of this book—philosophical, economical,
political—does not exactly coincide with my standpoint of to-day.
Modern international Socialism, since fully developed as a science,
chiefly and almost exclusively through the efforts of Marx, did not
as yet exist in 1844. My book represents one of the phases of its
embryonic development; and as the human embryo, in its early
stages, still reproduces the gill-arches of our fish-ancestors, so
this book exhibits everywhere the traces of the descent of modern
Socialism from one of its ancestors,—German philosophy. Thus great
stress is laid on the dictum that Communism is not a mere party
doctrine of the working-class, but a theory compassing the
emancipation of society at large, including the capitalist class,
from its present narrow conditions. This is true enough in the
abstract, but absolutely useless, and sometimes worse, in practice.
So long as the wealthy classes not only do not feel the want of any
emancipation, but strenuously oppose the self-emancipation of the
working-class, so long the social revolution will have to be
prepared and fought out by the working-class alone. The French
bourgeois of 1789, too, declared the emancipation of the
bourgeoisie to be the emancipation of the whole human race; but the
nobility and clergy would not see it; the proposition—though for
the time being, with respect to feudalism, an abstract historical
truth—soon became a mere sentimentalism, and disappeared from view
altogether in the fire of the revolutionary struggle. And to-day,
the very people who, from the “impartiality” of their superior
standpoint, preach to the workers a Socialism soaring high above
their class interests and class struggles, and tending to reconcile
in a higher humanity the interests of both the contending
classes—these people are either neophytes, who have still to learn
a great deal, or they are the worst enemies of the workers,—wolves
in sheeps’ clothing.
The recurring period of the great industrial crisis is stated in
the text as five years. This was the period apparently indicated by
the course of events from 1825 to 1842. But the industrial history
from 1842 to 1868 has shown that the real period is one of ten
years; that the intermediate revulsions were secondary, and tended
more and more to disappear. Since 1868 the state of things has
changed again, of which more anon.
I have taken care not to strike out of the text the many
prophecies, amongst others that of an imminent social revolution in
England, which my youthful ardour induced me to venture upon. The
wonder is, not that a good many of them proved wrong, but that so
many of them have proved right, and that the critical state of
English trade, to be brought on by Continental and especially
American competition, which I then foresaw—though in too short a
period—has now actually come to pass. In this respect I can, and am
bound to, bring the book up to date, by placing here an article
which I published in the London Commonweal of March 1, 1885, under
the heading: “England in 1845 and in 1885.” It gives at the same
time a short outline of the history of the English working-class
during these forty years, and is as follows:
“Forty years ago England stood face to face with a crisis, solvable
to all appearances by force only. The immense and rapid development
of manufactures had outstripped the extension of foreign markets
and the increase of demand. Every ten years the march of industry
was violently interrupted by a general commercial crash, followed,
after a long period of chronic depression, by a few short years of
prosperity, and always ending in feverish over-production and
consequent renewed collapse. The capitalist class clamoured for
Free Trade in corn, and threatened to enforce it by sending the
starving population of the towns back to the country districts
whence they came, to invade them, as John Bright said, not as
paupers begging for bread, but as an army quartered upon the enemy.
The working masses of the towns demanded their share of political
power—the People’s Charter; they were supported by the majority of
the small trading class, and the only difference between the two
was whether the Charter should be carried by physical or by moral
force. Then came the commercial crash of 1847 and the Irish famine,
and with both the prospect of revolution
“The French Revolution of 1848 saved the English middle-class. The
Socialistic pronunciamentos of the victorious French workmen
frightened the small middle-class of England and disorganised the
narrower, but more matter-of-fact movement of the English
working-class. At the very moment when Chartism was bound to assert
itself in its full strength, it collapsed internally, before even
it collapsed externally on the 10th of April, 1848. The action of
the working-class was thrust into the background. The capitalist
class triumphed along the whole line.
“The Reform Bill of 1831 had been the victory of the whole
capitalist class over the landed aristocracy. The repeal of the
Corn Laws was the victory of the manufacturing capitalist not only
over the landed aristocracy, but over those sections of
capitalists, too, whose interests were more or less bound up with
the landed interest,—bankers, stock-jobbers, fund-holders, etc.
Free Trade meant the re-adjustment of the whole home and foreign,
commercial and financial policy of England in accordance with the
interests of the manufacturing capitalists—the class which now
represented the nation. And they set about this task with a will.
Every obstacle to industrial production was mercilessly removed.
The tariff and the whole system of taxation were revolutionised.
Everything was made subordinate to one end, but that end of the
utmost importance to the manufacturing capitalist: the cheapening
of all raw produce, and especially of the means of living of the
working-class; the reduction of the cost of raw material, and the
keeping down—if not as yet the bringing down—of wages. England was
to become the ‘workshop of the world;’ all other countries were to
become for England what Ireland already was,—markets for her
manufactured goods, supplying her in return with raw materials and
food. England the great manufacturing centre of an agricultural
world, with an ever-increasing number of corn and cotton-growing
Irelands revolving around her, the industrial sun. What a glorious
prospect!
“The manufacturing capitalists set about the realisation of this
their great object with that strong common sense and that contempt
for traditional principles which has ever distinguished them from
their more narrow-minded compeers on the Continent. Chartism was
dying out. The revival of commercial prosperity, natural after the
revulsion of 1847 had spent itself, was put down altogether to the
credit of Free Trade. Both these circumstances had turned the
English working-class, politically, into the tail of the ‘great
Liberal party,’ the party led by the manufacturers. This advantage,
once gained, had to be perpetuated. And the manufacturing
capitalists, from the Chartist opposition, not to Free Trade, but
to the transformation of Free Trade into the one vital national
question, had learnt, and were learning more and more, that the
middle-class can never obtain full social and political power over
the nation except by the help of the working-class. Thus a gradual
change came over the relations between both classes. The Factory
Acts, once the bugbear of all manufacturers, were not only
willingly submitted to, but their expansion into acts regulating
almost all trades, was tolerated. Trades’ Unions, hitherto
considered inventions of the devil himself, were now petted and
patronised as perfectly legitimate institutions, and as useful
means of spreading sound economical doctrines amongst the workers.
Even strikes, than which nothing had been more nefarious up to
1848, were now gradually found out to be occasionally very useful,
especially when provoked by the masters themselves, at their own
time. Of the legal enactments, placing the workman at a lower level
or at a disadvantage with regard to the master, at least the most
revolting were repealed. And, practically, that horrid ‘People’s
Charter’ actually became the political programme of the very
manufacturers who had opposed it to the last. ‘The Abolition of the
Property Qualification’ and ‘Vote by Ballot’ are now the law of the
land. The Reform Acts of 1867 and 1884 make a near approach to
‘universal suffrage,’ at least such as it now exists in Germany;
the Redistribution Bill now before Parliament creates ‘equal
electoral districts’—on the whole not more unequal than those of
Germany; ‘payment of members,’ and shorter, if not actually ‘annual
Parliaments,’ are visibly looming in the distance—and yet there are
people who say that Chartism is dead.
“The Revolution of 1848, not less than many of its predecessors,
has had strange bedfellows and successors. The very people who put
it down have become, as Karl Marx used to say, its testamentary
executors. Louis Napoleon had to create an independent and united
Italy, Bismarck had to revolutionise Germany and to restore
Hungarian independence, and the English manufacturers had to enact
the People’s Charter.
“For England, the effects of this domination of the manufacturing
capitalists were at first startling. Trade revived and extended to
a degree unheard of even in this cradle of modern industry; the
previous astounding creations of steam and machinery dwindled into
nothing compared with the immense mass of productions of the twenty
years from 1850 to 1870, with the overwhelming figures of exports
and imports, of wealth accumulated in the hands of capitalists and
of human working power concentrated in the large towns. The
progress was indeed interrupted, as before, by a crisis every ten
years, in 1857 as well as in 1866; but these revulsions were now
considered as natural, inevitable events, which must be
fatalistically submitted to, and which always set themselves right
in the end.
“And the condition of the working-class during this period? There
was temporary improvement even for the great mass. But this
improvement always was reduced to the old level by the influx of
the great body of the unemployed reserve, by the constant
superseding of bands by new machinery, by the immigration of the
agricultural population, now, too, more and more superseded by
machines.
“A permanent improvement can be recognised for two ‘protected’
sections only of the working-class. Firstly, the factory hands. The
fixing by Act of Parliament of their working-day within relatively
rational limits has restored their physical constitution and
endowed them with a moral superiority, enhanced by their local
concentration. They are undoubtedly better off than before 1848.
The best proof is that, out of ten strikes they make, nine are
provoked by the manufacturers in their own interests, as the only
means of securing a reduced production. You can never get the
masters to agree to work ‘short time,’ let manufactured goods be
ever so unsaleable; but get the workpeople to strike, and the
masters shut their factories to a man.
“Secondly, the great Trades’ Unions. They are the organisations of
those trades in which the labour of grown-up men predominates, or
is alone applicable. Here the competition neither of women and
children nor of machinery has so far weakened their organised
strength. The engineers, the carpenters, and joiners, the
bricklayers, are each of them a power, to that extent that, as in
the case of the bricklayers and bricklayers’ labourers, they can
even successfully resist the introduction of machinery. That their
condition has remarkably improved since 1848 there can be no doubt,
and the best proof of this is in the fact, that for more than
fifteen years not only have their employers been with them, but
they with their employers, upon exceedingly good terms. They form
an aristocracy among the working-class; they have succeeded in
enforcing for themselves a relatively comfortable position, and
they accept it as final. They are the model working-men of Messrs.
Leone Levi & Giffen, and they are very nice people indeed
nowadays to deal with, for any sensible capitalist in particular
and for the whole capitalist class in general.
“But as to the great mass of working-people, the state of misery
and insecurity in which they live now is as low as ever, if not
lower. The East End of London is an everspreading pool of stagnant
misery and desolation, of starvation when out of work, and
degradation, physical and moral, when in work. And so in all other
large towns—abstraction made of the privileged minority of the
workers; and so in the smaller towns and in the agricultural
districts. The law which reduces the value of labour-power to the
value of the necessary means of subsistence, and the other law
which reduces its average price, as a rule, to the minimum of those
means of subsistence, these laws act upon them with the
irresistible force of an automatic engine, which crushes them
between its wheels.
“This, then, was the position created by the Free Trade policy of
1847, and by twenty years of the rule of the manufacturing
capitalists. But, then, a change came. The crash of 1866 was,
indeed, followed by a slight and short revival about 1873; but that
did not last. We did not, indeed, pass through the full crisis at
the time it was due, in 1877 or 1878; but we have had, ever since
1876, a chronic state of stagnation in all dominant branches of
industry. Neither will the full crash come; nor will the period of
longed-for prosperity to which we used to be entitled before and
after it. A dull depression, a chronic glut of all markets for all
trades, that is what we have been living in for nearly ten years.
How is this?
“The Free Trade theory was based upon one assumption: that England
was to be the one great manufacturing centre of an agricultural
world. And the actual fact is that this assumption has turned out
to be a pure delusion. The conditions of modern industry,
steam-power and machinery, can be established wherever there is
fuel, especially coals. And other countries beside England,—France,
Belgium, Germany, America, even Russia,—have coals. And the people
over there did not see the advantage of being turned into Irish
pauper farmers merely for the greater wealth and glory of English
capitalists. They set resolutely about manufacturing, not only for
themselves, but for the rest of the world; and the consequence is,
that the manufacturing monopoly enjoyed by England for nearly a
century is irretrievably broken up.
“But the manufacturing monopoly of England is the pivot of the
present social system of England. Even while that monopoly lasted,
the markets could not keep pace with the increasing productivity of
English manufacturers; the decennial crises were the consequence.
And new markets are getting scarcer every day, so much so that even
the negroes of the Congo are now to be forced into the civilisation
attendant upon Manchester calicos, Staffordshire pottery, and
Birmingham hardware. How will it be when Continental, and
especially American, goods flow in in ever-increasing
quantities—when the predominating share, still held by British
manufacturers, will become reduced from year to year? Answer, Free
Trade, thou universal panacea.
“I am not the first to point this out. Already, in 1883, at the
Southport meeting of the British Association, Mr. Inglis Palgrave,
the President of the Economic section, stated plainly that ‘the
days of great trade profits in England were over, and there was a
pause in the progress of several great branches of industrial
labour. The country might almost be said to be entering the
non-progressive state.’
“But what is to be the consequence? Capitalist production cannot
stop. It must go on increasing and expanding, or it must die. Even
now, the mere reduction of England’s lion’s share in the supply of
the world’s markets means stagnation, distress, excess of capital
here, excess of unemployed workpeople there. What will it be when
the increase of yearly production is brought to a complete
stop?
“Here is the vulnerable place, the heel of Achilles, for
capitalistic production. Its very basis is the necessity of
constant expansion, and this constant expansion now becomes
impossible. It ends in a deadlock. Every year England is brought
nearer face to face with the question: either the country must go
to pieces, or capitalist production must. Which is it to be?
“And the working-class? If even under the unparalleled commercial
and industrial expansion, from 1848 to 1866, they have had to
undergo such misery; if even then the great bulk of them
experienced at best but a temporary improvement of their condition,
while only a small, privileged, ‘protected’ minority was
permanently benefited, what will it be when this dazzling period is
brought finally to a close; when the present dreary stagnation
shall not only become intensified, but this, its intensified
condition, shall become the permanent and normal state of English
trade?
“The truth is this: during the period of England’s industrial
monopoly the English working-class have, to a certain extent,
shared in the benefits of the monopoly. These benefits were very
unequally parcelled out amongst them; the privileged minority
pocketed most, but even the great mass had, at least, a temporary
share now and then. And that is the reason why, since the dying-out
of Owenism, there has been no Socialism in England. With the
breakdown of that monopoly, the English working-class will lose
that privileged position; it will find itself generally—the
privileged and leading minority not excepted—on a level with its
fellow-workers abroad. And that is the reason why there will be
Socialism again in England.”
To this statement of the case, as that case appeared to me in 1885,
I have but little to add. Needless to say that to-day there is
indeed “Socialism again in England,” and plenty of it—Socialism of
all shades: Socialism conscious and unconscious, Socialism prosaic
and poetic, Socialism of the working-class and of the middle-class,
for, verily, that abomination of abominations, Socialism, has not
only become respectable, but has actually donned evening dress and
lounges lazily on drawing-room causeuses. That shows the incurable
fickleness of that terrible despot of “society,” middle-class
public opinion, and once more justifies the contempt in which we
Socialists of a past generation always held that public opinion. At
the same time, we have no reason to grumble at the symptom
itself.
What I consider far more important than this momentary fashion
among bourgeois circles of affecting a mild dilution of Socialism,
and even more than the actual progress Socialism has made in
England generally, that is the revival of the East End of London.
That immense haunt of misery is no longer the stagnant pool it was
six years ago. It has shaken off its torpid despair, has returned
to life, and has become the home of what is called the “New
Unionism;” that is to say, of the organisation of the great mass of
“unskilled” workers. This organisation may to a great extent adopt
the form of the old Unions of “skilled” workers, but it is
essentially different in character. The old Unions preserve the
traditions of the time when they were founded, and look upon the
wages system as a once for all established, final fact, which they
at best can modify in the interest of their members. The new Unions
were founded at a time when the faith in the eternity of the wages
system was severely shaken; their founders and promoters were
Socialists either consciously or by feeling; the masses, whose
adhesion gave them strength, were rough, neglected, looked down
upon by the working-class aristocracy; but they had this immense
advantage, that their minds were virgin soil, entirely free from
the inherited “respectable” bourgeois prejudices which hampered the
brains of the better situated “old” Unionists. And thus we see now
these new Unions taking the lead of the working-class movement
generally, and more and more taking in tow the rich and proud “old”
Unions.
Undoubtedly, the East Enders have committed colossal blunders; so
have their predecessors, and so do the doctrinaire Socialists who
pooh-pooh them. A large class, like a great nation, never learns
better or quicker than by undergoing the consequences of its own
mistakes. And for all the faults committed in past, present, and
future, the revival of the East End of London remains one of the
greatest and most fruitful facts of this fin de siècle, and glad
and proud I am to have lived to see it.
F. Engels.
INTRODUCTION
The history of the proletariat in England begins with the second
half of the last century, with the invention of the steam-engine
and of machinery for working cotton. These inventions gave rise, as
is well known, to an industrial revolution, a revolution which
altered the whole civil society; one, the historical importance of
which is only now beginning to be recognised. England is the
classic soil of this transformation, which was all the mightier,
the more silently it proceeded; and England is, therefore, the
classic land of its chief product also, the proletariat. Only in
England can the proletariat be studied in all its relations and
from all sides.
We have not, here and now, to deal with the history of this
revolution, nor with its vast importance for the present and the
future. Such a delineation must be reserved for a future, more
comprehensive work. For the moment, we must limit ourselves to the
little that is necessary for understanding the facts that follow,
for comprehending the present state of the English
proletariat.
Before the introduction of machinery, the spinning and weaving of
raw materials was carried on in the working-man’s home. Wife and
daughter spun the yarn that the father wove or that they sold, if
he did not work it up himself. These weaver families lived in the
country in the neighbourhood of the towns, and could get on fairly
well with their wages, because the home market was almost the only
one, and the crushing power of competition that came later, with
the conquest of foreign markets and the extension of trade, did not
yet press upon wages. There was, further, a constant increase in
the demand for the home market, keeping pace with the slow increase
in population and employing all the workers; and there was also the
impossibility of vigorous competition of the workers among
themselves, consequent upon the rural dispersion of their homes. So
it was that the weaver was usually in a position to lay by
something, and rent a little piece of land, that he cultivated in
his leisure hours, of which he had as many as he chose to take,
since he could weave whenever and as long as he pleased. True, he
was a bad farmer and managed his land inefficiently, often
obtaining but poor crops; nevertheless, he was no proletarian, he
had a stake in the country, he was permanently settled, and stood
one step higher in society than the English workman of
to-day.
So the workers vegetated throughout a passably comfortable
existence, leading a righteous and peaceful life in all piety and
probity; and their material position was far better than that of
their successors. They did not need to overwork; they did no more
than they chose to do, and yet earned what they needed. They had
leisure for healthful work in garden or field, work which, in
itself, was recreation for them, and they could take part besides
in the recreations and games of their neighbours, and all these
games—bowling, cricket, football, etc., contributed to their
physical health and vigour. They were, for the most part, strong,
well-built people, in whose physique little or no difference from
that of their peasant neighbours was discoverable. Their children
grew up in the fresh country air, and, if they could help their
parents at work, it was only occasionally; while of eight or twelve
hours work for them there was no question.
What the moral and intellectual character of this class was may be
guessed. Shut off from the towns, which they never entered, their
yarn and woven stuff being delivered to travelling agents for
payment of wages—so shut off that old people who lived quite in the
neighbourhood of the town never went thither until they were robbed
of their trade by the introduction of machinery and obliged to look
about them in the towns for work—the weavers stood upon the moral
and intellectual plane of the yeomen with whom they were usually
immediately connected through their little holdings. They regarded
their squire, the greatest landholder of the region, as their
natural superior; they asked advice of him, laid their small
disputes before him for settlement, and gave him all honour, as
this patriarchal relation involved. They were “respectable” people,
good husbands and fathers, led moral lives because they had no
temptation to be immoral, there being no groggeries or low houses
in their vicinity, and because the host, at whose inn they now and
then quenched their thirst, was also a respectable man, usually a
large tenant farmer who took pride in his good order, good beer,
and early hours. They had their children the whole day at home, and
brought them up in obedience and the fear of God; the patriarchal
relationship remained undisturbed so long as the children were
unmarried. The young people grew up in idyllic simplicity and
intimacy with their playmates until they married; and even though
sexual intercourse before marriage almost unfailingly took place,
this happened only when the moral obligation of marriage was
recognised on both sides, and a subsequent wedding made everything
good. In short, the English industrial workers of those days lived
and thought after the fashion still to be found here and there in
Germany, in retirement and seclusion, without mental activity and
without violent fluctuations in their position in life. They could
rarely read and far more rarely write; went regularly to church,
never talked politics, never conspired, never thought, delighted in
physical exercises, listened with inherited reverence when the
Bible was read, and were, in their unquestioning humility,
exceedingly well-disposed towards the “superior” classes. But
intellectually, they were dead; lived only for their petty, private
interest, for their looms and gardens, and knew nothing of the
mighty movement which, beyond their horizon, was sweeping through
mankind. They were comfortable in their silent vegetation, and but
for the industrial revolution they would never have emerged from
this existence, which, cosily romantic as it was, was nevertheless
not worthy of human beings. In truth, they were not human beings;
they were merely toiling machines in the service of the few
aristocrats who had guided history down to that time. The
industrial revolution has simply carried this out to its logical
end by making the workers machines pure and simple, taking from
them the last trace of independent activity, and so forcing them to
think and demand a position worthy of men. As in France politics,
so in England manufacture, and the movement of civil society in
general drew into the whirl of history the last classes which had
remained sunk in apathetic indifference to the universal interests
of mankind.
The first invention which gave rise to a radical change in the
state of the English workers was the jenny, invented in the year
1764 by a weaver, James Hargreaves, of Standhill, near Blackburn,
in North Lancashire. This machine was the rough beginning of the
later invented mule, and was moved by hand. Instead of one spindle
like the ordinary spinning-wheel, it carried sixteen or eighteen
manipulated by a single workman. This invention made it possible to
deliver more yarn than heretofore. Whereas, though one weaver had
employed three spinners, there had never been enough yarn, and the
weaver had often been obliged to wait for it, there was now more
yarn to be had than could be woven by the available workers. The
demand for woven goods, already increasing, rose yet more in
consequence of the cheapness of these goods, which cheapness, in
turn, was the outcome of the diminished cost of producing the yarn.
More weavers were needed, and weavers’ wages rose. Now that the
weaver could earn more at his loom, he gradually abandoned his
farming, and gave his whole time to weaving. At that time a family
of four grown persons and two children (who were set to spooling)
could earn, with eight hours’ daily work, four pounds sterling in a
week, and often more if trade was good and work pressed. It
happened often enough that a single weaver earned two pounds a week
at his loom. By degrees the class of farming weavers wholly
disappeared, and was merged in the newly arising class of weavers
who lived wholly upon wages, had no property whatever, not even the
pretended property of a holding, and so became working-men,
proletarians. Moreover, the old relation between spinner and weaver
was destroyed. Hitherto, so far as this had been possible, yarn had
been spun and woven under one roof. Now that the jenny as well as
the loom required a strong hand, men began to spin, and whole
families lived by spinning, while others laid the antiquated,
superseded spinning-wheel aside; and, if they had not means of
purchasing a jenny, were forced to live upon the wages of the
father alone. Thus began with spinning and weaving that division of
labour which has since been so infinitely perfected.
While the industrial proletariat was thus developing with the first
still very imperfect machine, the same machine gave rise to the
agricultural proletariat. There had, hitherto, been a vast number
of small landowners, yeomen, who had vegetated in the same
unthinking quiet as their neighbours, the farming weavers. They
cultivated their scraps of land quite after the ancient and
inefficient fashion of their ancestors, and opposed every change
with the obstinacy peculiar to such creatures of habit, after
remaining stationary from generation to generation. Among them were
many small holders also, not tenants in the present sense of the
word, but people who had their land handed down from their fathers,
either by hereditary lease, or by force of ancient custom, and had
hitherto held it as securely as if it had actually been their own
property. When the industrial workers withdrew from agriculture, a
great number of small holdings fell idle, and upon these the new
class of large tenants established themselves, tenants-at-will,
holding fifty, one hundred, two hundred or more acres, liable to be
turned out at the end of the year, but able by improved tillage and
larger farming to increase the yield of the land. They could sell
their produce more cheaply than the yeomen, for whom nothing
remained when his farm no longer supported him but to sell it,
procure a jenny or a loom, or take service as an agricultural
labourer in the employ of a large farmer. His inherited slowness
and the inefficient methods of cultivation bequeathed by his
ancestors, and above which he could not rise, left him no
alternative when forced to compete with men who managed their
holdings on sounder principles and with all the advantages bestowed
by farming on a large scale and the investment of capital for the
improvement of the soil.
Meanwhile, the industrial movement did not stop here. Single
capitalists began to set up spinning jennies in great buildings and
to use water-power for driving them, so placing themselves in a
position to diminish the number of workers, and sell their yarn
more cheaply than single spinners could do who moved their own
machines by hand. There were constant improvements in the jenny, so
that machines continually became antiquated, and must be altered or
even laid aside; and though the capitalists could hold out by the
application of water-power even with the old machinery, for the
single spinner this was impossible. And the factory system, the
beginning of which was thus made, received a fresh extension in
1767, through the spinning throstle invented by Richard Arkwright,
a barber, in Preston, in North Lancashire. After the steam-engine,
this is the most important mechanical invention of the 18th
century. It was calculated from the beginning for mechanical motive
power, and was based upon wholly new principles. By the combination
of the peculiarities of the jenny and throstle, Samuel Crompton, of
Firwood, Lancashire, contrived the mule in 1785, and as Arkwright
invented the carding engine, and preparatory (“slubbing and
roving”) frames about the same time, the factory system became the
prevailing one for the spinning of cotton. By means of trifling
modifications these machines were gradually adapted to the spinning
of flax, and so to the superseding of hand-work here, too. But even
then, the end was not yet. In the closing years of the last
century, Dr. Cartwright, a country parson, had invented the
power-loom, and about 1804 had so far perfected it, that it could
successfully compete with the hand-weaver; and all this machinery
was made doubly important by James Watt’s steam-engine, invented in
1764, and used for supplying motive power for spinning since
1785.
With these inventions, since improved from year to year, the
victory of machine-work over hand-work in the chief branches of
English industry was won; and the history of the latter from that
time forward simply relates how the hand-workers have been driven
by machinery from one position after another. The consequences of
this were, on the one hand, a rapid fall in price of all
manufactured commodities, prosperity of commerce and manufacture,
the conquest of nearly all the unprotected foreign markets, the
sudden multiplication of capital and national wealth; on the other
hand, a still more rapid multiplication of the proletariat, the
destruction of all property-holding and of all security of
employment for the working-class, demoralisation, political
excitement, and all those facts so highly repugnant to Englishmen
in comfortable circumstances, which we shall have to consider in
the following pages. Having already seen what a transformation in
the social condition of the lower classes a single such clumsy
machine as the jenny had wrought, there is no cause for surprise as
to that which a complete and interdependent system of finely
adjusted machinery has brought about, machinery which receives raw
material and turns out woven goods.
Meanwhile, let us trace the development of English manufacture
somewhat more minutely, beginning with the cotton industry. In the
years 1771-1775, there were annually imported into England rather
less than 5,000,000 pounds of raw cotton; in the year 1841 there
were imported 528,000,000 pounds, and the import for 1844 will
reach at least 600,000,000 pounds. In 1834 England exported
556,000,000 yards of woven cotton goods, 76,500,000 pounds of
cotton yarn, and cotton hosiery of the value of £1,200,000. In the
same year over 8,000,000 mule spindles were at work, 110,000 power
and 250,000 hand-looms, throstle spindles not included, in the
service of the cotton industry; and, according to MacCulloch’s
reckoning, nearly a million and a half human beings were supported
by this branch, of whom but 220,000 worked in the mills; the power
used in these mills was steam, equivalent to 33,000 horse-power,
and water, equivalent to 11,000 horse-power. At present these
figures are far from adequate, and it may be safely assumed that,
in the year 1845, the power and number of the machines and the
number of the workers is greater by one-half than it was in 1834.
The chief centre of this industry is Lancashire, where it
originated; it has thoroughly revolutionised this county,
converting it from an obscure, ill-cultivated swamp into a busy,
lively region, multiplying its population tenfold in eighty years,
and causing giant cities such as Liverpool and Manchester,
containing together 700,000 inhabitants, and their neighbouring
towns, Bolton with 60,000, Rochdale with 75,000, Oldham with
50,000, Preston with 60,000, Ashton and Stalybridge with 40,000,
and a whole list of other manufacturing towns to spring up as if by
a magic touch. The history of South Lancashire contains some of the
greatest marvels of modern times, yet no one ever mentions them,
and all these miracles are the product of the cotton industry.
Glasgow, too, the centre for the cotton district of Scotland, for
Lanarkshire and Renfrewshire, has increased in population from
30,000 to 300,000 since the introduction of the industry. The
hosiery manufacture of Nottingham and Derby also received one fresh
impulse from the lower price of yarn, and a second one from an
improvement of the stocking loom, by means of which two stockings
could be woven at once. The manufacture of lace, too, became an
important branch of industry after the invention of the lace
machine in 1777; soon after that date Lindley invented the
point-net machine, and in 1809 Heathcote invented the bobbin-net
machine, in consequence of which the production of lace was greatly
simplified, and the demand increased proportionately in consequence
of the diminished cost, so that now, at least 200,000 persons are
supported by this industry. Its chief centres are Nottingham,
Leicester, and the West of England, Wiltshire, Devonshire, etc. A
corresponding extension has taken place in the branches dependent
upon the cotton industry, in dyeing, bleaching, and printing.
Bleaching by the application of chlorine in place of the oxygen of
the atmosphere; dyeing and printing by the rapid development of
chemistry, and printing by a series of most brilliant mechanical
inventions, a yet greater advance which, with the extension of
these branches caused by the growth of the cotton industry, raised
them to a previously unknown degree of prosperity.
The same activity manifested itself in the manufacture of wool.
This had hitherto been the leading department of English industry,
but the quantities formerly produced are as nothing in comparison
with that which is now manufactured. In 1782 the whole wool crop of
the preceding three years lay unused for want of workers, and would
have continued so to lie if the newly invented machinery had not
come to its assistance and spun it. The adaptation of this
machinery to the spinning of wool was most successfully
accomplished. Then began the same sudden development in the wool
district, which we have already seen in the cotton districts. In
1738 there were 75,000 pieces of woollen cloth produced in the West
Riding of Yorkshire; in 1817 there were 490,000 pieces, and so
rapid was the extension of the industry that in 1834, 450,000 more
pieces were produced than in 1825. In 1801, 101,000,000 pounds of
wool (7,000,000 pounds of it imported) were worked up; in 1835,
180,000,000 pounds were worked up; of which 42,000,000 pounds were
imported. The principal centre of this industry is the West Riding
of Yorkshire, where, especially at Bradford, long English wool is
converted into worsted yarns, etc.; while in the other cities,
Leeds, Halifax, Huddersfield, etc., short wool is converted into
hard-spun yarn and cloth. Then come the adjacent part of
Lancashire, the region of Rochdale, where in addition to the cotton
industry much flannel is produced, and the West of England which
supplies the finest cloths. Here also the growth of population is
worthy of observation:
Bradford contained in 1801 29,000, and in 1831 77,000
inhabitants.
Halifax ,, ,, 68,000, ,, ,, 110,000 ,,
Huddersfield ,, ,, 15,000, ,, ,, 34,000 ,,
Leeds,, ,, 53,000, ,, ,, 123,000 ,,
And the whole West Riding 564,000, ,, ,, 980,000 ,,
A population which, since 1831, must have increased at least 20 to
25 per cent. further. In 1835 the spinning of wool employed in the
United Kingdom 1,313 mills, with 71,300 workers, these last being
but a small portion of the multitude who are supported p.
10directly or indirectly by the manufacture of wool, and excluding
nearly all weavers.
Progress in the linen trade developed later, because the nature of
the raw material made the application of spinning machinery very
difficult. Attempts had been made in the last years of the last
century in Scotland, but the Frenchman, Girard, who introduced flax
spinning in 1810, was the first who succeeded practically, and even
Girard’s machines first attained on British soil the importance
they deserved by means of improvements which they underwent in
England, and of their universal application in Leeds, Dundee, and
Belfast. From this time the British linen trade rapidly extended.
In 1814, 3,000 tons of flax were imported; in 1833, nearly 19,000
tons of flax and 3,400 tons of hemp. The export of Irish linen to
Great Britain rose from 32,000,000 yards in 1800 to 53,000,000 in
1825, of which a large part was re-exported. The export of English
and Scotch woven linen goods rose from 24,000,000 yards in 1820 to
51,000,000 yards in 1833. The number of flax spinning
establishments in 1835 was 347, employing 33,000 workers, of which
one-half were in the South of Scotland, more than 60 in the West
Riding of Yorkshire, Leeds, and its environs, 25 in Belfast,
Ireland, and the rest in Dorset and Lancashire. Weaving is carried
on in the South of Scotland, here and there in England, but
principally in Ireland.
With like success did the English turn their attention to the
manufacture of silk. Raw material was imported from Southern Europe
and Asia ready spun, and the chief labour lay in the twisting of
fine threads. Until 1824 the heavy import duty, four shillings per
pound on raw material, greatly retarded the development of the
English silk industry, while only the markets of England and the
Colonies were protected for it. In that year the duty was reduced
to one penny, and the number of mills at once largely increased. In
a single year the number of throwing spindles rose from 780,000 to
1,180,000; and, although the commercial crisis of 1825 crippled
this branch of industry for the moment, yet in 1827 more was
produced than ever, the mechanical skill and experience of the
English having secured their twisting machinery the supremacy over
the awkward devices of their competitors. In 1835 the British
Empire possessed 263 twisting mills, employing 30,000 workers,
located chiefly in Cheshire, in Macclesfield, Congleton, and the
surrounding districts, and in Manchester and Somersetshire. Besides
these, there are numerous mills for working up waste, from which a
peculiar article known as spun silk is manufactured, with which the
English supply even the Paris and Lyons weavers. The weaving of the
silk so twisted and spun is carried on in Paisley and elsewhere in
Scotland, and in Spitalfields, London, but also in Manchester and
elsewhere. Nor is the gigantic advance achieved in English
manufacture since 1760 restricted to the production of clothing
materials. The impulse, once given, was communicated to all
branches of industrial activity, and a multitude of inventions
wholly unrelated to those here cited, received double importance
from the fact that they were made in the midst of the universal
movement. But as soon as the immeasurable importance of mechanical
power was practically demonstrated, every energy was concentrated
in the effort to exploit this power in all directions, and to
exploit it in the interest of individual inventors and
manufacturers; and the demand for machinery, fuel, and materials
called a mass of workers and a number of trades into redoubled
activity. The steam-engine first gave importance to the broad
coal-fields of England; the production of machinery began now for
the first time, and with it arose a new interest in the iron mines
which supplied raw material for it. The increased consumption of
wool stimulated English sheep breeding, and the growing importation
of wool, flax, and silk called forth an extension of the British
ocean carrying trade. Greatest of all was the growth of production
of iron. The rich iron deposits of the English hills had hitherto
been little developed; iron had always been smelted by means of
charcoal, which became gradually more expensive as agriculture
improved and forests were cut away. The beginning of the use of
coke in iron smelting had been made in the last century, and in
1780 a new method was invented of converting into available
wrought-iron coke-smelted iron, which up to that time had been
convertible into cast-iron p. 12only. This process, known as
“puddling,” consists in withdrawing the carbon which had mixed with
the iron during the process of smelting, and opened a wholly new
field for the production of English iron. Smelting furnaces were
built fifty times larger than before, the process of smelting was
simplified by the introduction of hot blasts, and iron could thus
be produced so cheaply that a multitude of objects which had before
been made of stone or wood were now made of iron.
In 1788, Thomas Paine, the famous democrat, built in Yorkshire the
first iron bridge, which was followed by a great number of others,
so that now nearly all bridges, especially for railroad traffic,
are built of cast-iron, while in London itself a bridge across the
Thames, the Southwark bridge, has been built of this material. Iron
pillars, supports for machinery, etc., are universally used, and
since the introduction of gas-lighting and railroads, new outlets
for English iron products are opened. Nails and screws gradually
came to be made by machinery. Huntsman, a Sheffielder, discovered
in 1790 a method for casting steel, by which much labour was saved,
and the production of wholly new cheap goods rendered practicable;
and through the greater purity of the material placed at its
disposal, and the more perfect tools, new machinery and minute
division of labour, the metal trade of England now first attained
importance. The population of Birmingham grew from 73,000 in 1801
to 200,000 in 1844; that of Sheffield from 46,000 in 1801 to
110,000 in 1844, and the consumption of coal in the latter city
alone reached in 1836, 515,000 tons. In 1805 there were exported
4,300 tons of iron products and 4,600 tons of pig-iron; in 1834,
16,200 tons of iron products and 107,000 tons of pig-iron, while
the whole iron product reaching in 1740 but 17,000 tons, had risen
in 1834 to nearly 700,000 tons. The smelting of pig-iron alone
consumes yearly more than 3,000,000 tons of coal, and the
importance which coal mining has attained in the course of the last
60 years can scarcely be conceived. All the English and Scotch
deposits are now worked, and the mines of Northumberland and Durham
alone yield annually more than 5,000,000 tons for shipping, and
employ from 40 to 50,000 men. According to the Durham Chronicle,
there were worked in these two counties: In 1753, 14 mines; in
1800, 40 mines; in 1836, 76 mines; in 1843, 130 mines. Moreover,
all mines are now much more energetically worked than formerly. A
similarly increased activity was applied to the working of tin,
copper, and lead, and alongside of the extension of glass
manufacture arose a new branch of industry in the production of
pottery, rendered important by the efforts of Josiah Wedgewood,
about 1763. This inventor placed the whole manufacture of stoneware
on a scientific basis, introduced better taste, and founded the
potteries of North Staffordshire, a district of eight English miles
square, which, formerly a desert waste, is now sown with works and
dwellings, and supports more than 60,000 people.
Into this universal whirl of activity everything was drawn.
Agriculture made a corresponding advance. Not only did landed
property pass, as we have already seen, into the hands of new
owners and cultivators, agriculture was affected in still another
way. The great holders applied capital to the improvement of the
soil, tore down needless fences, drained, manured, employed better
tools, and applied a rotation of crops. The progress of science
came to their assistance also; Sir Humphrey Davy applied chemistry
to agriculture with success, and the development of mechanical
science bestowed a multitude of advantages upon the large farmer.
Further, in consequence of the increase of population, the demand
for agricultural products increased in such measure that from 1760
to 1834, 6,840,540 acres of waste land were reclaimed; and, in
spite of this, England was transformed from a grain exporting to a
grain importing country.
The same activity was developed in the establishment of
communication. From 1818 to 1829, there were built in England and
Wales, 1,000 English miles of roadway of the width prescribed by
law, 60 feet, and nearly all the old roads were reconstructed on
the new system of M’Adam. In Scotland, the Department of Public
Works built since 1803 nearly 900 miles of roadway and more than
1,000 bridges, by which the population of the Highlands was
suddenly placed within reach of civilisation. The Highlanders had
hitherto been chiefly poachers and smugglers; they now became
farmers and hand-workers. And, though Gaelic schools were organised
for the purpose of maintaining the Gaelic language, yet
Gaelic-Celtic customs and speech are rapidly vanishing before the
approach of English civilisation. So, too, in Ireland; between the
counties of Cork, Limerick, and Kerry, lay hitherto a wilderness
wholly without passable roads, and serving, by reason of its
inaccessibility, as the refuge of all criminals and the chief
protection of the Celtic Irish nationality in the South of Ireland.
It has now been cut through by public roads, and civilisation has
thus gained admission even to this savage region. The whole British
Empire, and especially England, which, sixty years ago, had as bad
roads as Germany or France then had, is now covered by a network of
the finest roadways; and these, too, like almost everything else in
England, are the work of private enterprise, the State having done
very little in this direction.
Before 1755 England possessed almost no canals. In that year a
canal was built in Lancashire from Sankey Brook to St Helen’s; and
in 1759, James Brindley built the first important one, the Duke of
Bridgewater’s canal from Manchester, and the coal mines of the
district to the mouth of the Mersey passing, near Barton, by
aqueduct, over the river Irwell. From this achievement dates the
canal building of England, to which Brindley first gave importance.
Canals were now built, and rivers made navigable in all directions.
In England alone, there are 2,200 miles of canals and 1,800 miles
of navigable river. In Scotland, the Caledonian Canal was cut
directly across the country, and in Ireland several canals were
built. These improvements, too, like the railroads and roadways,
are nearly all the work of private individuals and companies.
The railroads have been only recently built. The first great one
was opened from Liverpool to Manchester in 1830, since which all
the great cities have been connected by rail. London with
Southampton, Brighton, Dover, Colchester, Exeter, and Birmingham;
Birmingham with Gloucester, Liverpool, Lancaster (via Newton and
Wigan, and via Manchester and Bolton); also with Leeds (via
Manchester and Halifax, and via Leicester, Derby, and p.
15Sheffield); Leeds with Hull and Newcastle (via York). There are
also many minor lines building or projected, which will soon make
it possible to travel from Edinburgh to London in one day.
As it had transformed the means of communication by land, so did
the introduction of steam revolutionise travel by sea. The first
steamboat was launched in 1807, in the Hudson, in North America;
the first in the British empire, in 1811, on the Clyde. Since then,
more than 600 have been built in England; and in 1836 more than 500
were plying to and from British ports.
Such, in brief, is the history of English industrial development in
the past sixty years, a history which has no counterpart in the
annals of humanity. Sixty, eighty years ago, England was a country
like every other, with small towns, few and simple industries, and
a thin but proportionally large agricultural population. To-day it
is a country like no other, with a capital of two and a half
million inhabitants; with vast manufacturing cities; with an
industry that supplies the world, and produces almost everything by
means of the most complex machinery; with an industrious,
intelligent, dense population, of which two-thirds are employed in
trade and commerce, and composed of classes wholly different;
forming, in fact, with other customs and other needs, a different
nation from the England of those days. The industrial revolution is
of the same importance for England as the political revolution for
France, and the philosophical revolution for Germany; and the
difference between England in 1760 and in 1844 is at least as great
as that between France, under the ancien régime and during the
revolution of July. But the mightiest result of this industrial
transformation is the English proletariat.
We have already seen how the proletariat was called into existence
by the introduction of machinery. The rapid extension of
manufacture demanded hands, wages rose, and troops of workmen
migrated from the agricultural districts to the towns. Population
multiplied enormously, and nearly all the increase took place in
the proletariat. Further, Ireland had entered upon an orderly
development only since the beginning of the eighteenth century.
There, too, the population, more than decimated by English p.
16cruelty in earlier disturbances, now rapidly multiplied,
especially after the advance in manufacture began to draw masses of
Irishmen towards England. Thus arose the great manufacturing and
commercial cities of the British Empire, in which at least
three-fourths of the population belong to the working-class, while
the lower middle-class consists only of small shopkeepers, and very
very few handicraftsmen. For, though the rising manufacture first
attained importance by transforming tools into machines, workrooms
into factories, and consequently, the toiling lower middle-class
into the toiling proletariat, and the former large merchants into
manufacturers, though the lower middle-class was thus early crushed
out, and the population reduced to the two opposing elements,
workers and capitalists, this happened outside of the domain of
manufacture proper, in the province of handicraft and retail trade
as well. In the place of the former masters and apprentices, came
great capitalists and working-men who had no prospect of rising
above their class. Hand-work was carried on after the fashion of
factory work, the division of labour was strictly applied, and
small employers who could not compete with great establishments
were forced down into the proletariat. At the same time the
destruction of the former organisation of hand-work, and the
disappearance of the lower middle-class deprived the working-man of
all possibility of rising into the middle-class himself. Hitherto
he had always had the prospect of establishing himself somewhere as
master artificer, perhaps employing journeymen and apprentices; but
now, when master artificers were crowded out by manufacturers, when
large capital had become necessary for carrying on work
independently, the working-class became, for the first time, an
integral, permanent class of the population, whereas it had
formerly often been merely a transition leading to the bourgeoisie.
Now, he who was born to toil had no other prospect than that of
remaining a toiler all his life. Now, for the first time,
therefore, the proletariat was in a position to undertake an
independent movement.